Articles from the June 2013 issue of the Industrial Worker, the newspaper of the revolutionary union, the Industrial Workers of the World (IWW).
Industrial Worker (June 2013)
For paper subscription info, please visit the IW page at iww.org
For a PDF copy of this issue, check here
What’s needed for effective industrial unionism
A response by Arthur Miller to “Staughton Lynd Responds To Counterpoint On Planks”, which appeared in the April 2013 Industrial Worker.
I do not misunderstand Staughton Lynd, I just have a different point of view. If our Preamble only spoke of industrial unionism I could understand his point of view, but it includes much more. Yes, the United Mine Workers (UMW), as is most all industrial unions in the AFL-CIO, is a far too top-down organization. That is not the fault of industrial unionism, but rather the fault of top-down unionism, of which the trade unions are mostly the same.
Still, even there I would say having industrial unions is far better than trade unions. I know this firsthand because since 1972, for the most part, I have belonged to other unions besides the IWW. Most of them were trade unions. In construction trade unions, they have been forced to create a bit of a hybrid form of industrial unionism between the Building Trades and Metal Trades Councils. But even with that, the trade union side of thinking sometimes wins out. I experienced that two times. Once during a Metal Trades strike that lasted eight-and-a-half months, when one of the unions signed their own contract and crossed the picket line of the other unions. Another time one union, the Boilermakers, signed a contract that left the other workers locked out for over a year.
Think about how things would have been if mining, auto, steel and so on organized by trade rather than by industry. You think things are bad now, it would be far worse if that had not happened. My point is that industrial unionism needs to be our union structure, but it does not stop there. There are many other things that are needed for good revolutionary unionism.
It is true, in my view, that “conventional labor unions would not seek radical structural change.” That is why we workers need the IWW and its unconventional revolutionary industrial unionism. As a long time dual carder it has been my view for over 40 years that the AFL-CIO cannot be reformed.
Yes, in modern times the IWW has been a bit weak at explaining its practices and ideas. Heck, all but one of our official literature items is out of print. And that is a big problem because I believe that we don’t only organize bargaining units, we also need to create Wobblies.
As to the term “to organize,” I think we have a different view on that. I believe that the role of organizers, that is good organizers, is to organize themselves out of a job. In other words, their job is to organize the workers so that they, the workers of a shop, can take over all the union work of their shop and branch when they are able to. The idea that workers should only organize themselves and once they do that we are willing to accompany them will not work often in the real world and would put off the workers taking control of their labor forever.
Arthur J. Miller, just an old retired shipyard worker
Originally appeared in the Industrial Worker (June 2013)
Comments
Venture syndicalism: can reviving the strike revive mass unionization?
A short article by Nate Hawthorne on the prospects of AFL-CIO unions taking bigger risks to halt the decline of unionization rates.
It’s surprising how small a fraction of U.S. workers are actually in labor unions. Just over 7 million government employees are union members and slightly fewer private sector employees are in unions. This means that just under 12 percent of public sector workers and less than 7 percent of private sector workers are in unions. These numbers keep falling.
If unions want to reverse their decline, they need to return to powerful strikes that stop businesses completely. That’s what Joe Burns argues in his recent book, “Reviving the Strike.” It’s a good book and I recommend it highly to all IWW members (it would pair very well with “Labor Law for the Rank and Filer” by Staughton Lynd and Daniel Gross). Burns supplies a concise and clear argument about the role of labor law in the decline of unions. The labor law system doesn’t work for unions, so if the unions want to continue to exist, they need to start breaking the law, he argues. There are big risks to breaking the law, though. Burns suggests that unions can get around this by setting up and funding fully independent organizations that will have fewer resources, and less to lose as a result. We may be seeing versions of this already, with the strikes against Walmart warehouse subcontractors, United Food and Commercial Workers (UFCW) and the Service Employees International Union (SEIU) organizing against Walmart and fast food respectively and union support for workers’ centers.
We might call this “venture syndicalism,” named after venture capitalism. Venture capital firms are companies that advance money to businesses that are in their very early stages, when they have little money, lots of risk of failure yet a high potential for success. The funds spent are a great deal of money for the startup company but only a small amount of money for a large financial company. Venture syndicalism is the union version of this, where the mainstream and wealthier unions fund more confrontational efforts than they can afford to carry out on their own.
Radicals have an important role to play in this effort. Both venture capitalism and venture syndicalism rely on a lot of initial unpaid hours by volunteers excited about the project for reasons beyond short-term financial gain. Burns suggests that most people join unions if and when it’s in their economic interest to do so. Unions in the United States are not going to have the power to win much unless there’s a threat of really serious economic harm to employers. That means unions are unlikely to act in ways that make the benefits of forming a union outweigh the costs for most people.
If people join unions based on costbenefit analysis then there’s little reason why anyone would ever take such actions. There’s a sort of “Which came first, the chicken or the egg?” quality to all this; most people won’t join unions unless there’s some benefit to doing so, yet the law is set up so that unions behave in ways that limit the benefits of unionization. Breaking the law will have huge costs, so why would people break the law?
The solution to the puzzle is that some people need to take militant action despite the risks, and not primarily out of a narrow cost-benefit analysis. I think this is part of the role that radicals can play in helping set off movements to enliven the existing labor movement. Some people might run the risks of initial militancy despite the consequences. In doing so, they push against the current prevailing forms of governing capitalism. If these initial efforts succeed, larger numbers can join in and the rules of the game will change, encouraging larger numbers of workers to form unions. That is to say it is often not in workers’ short-term interests, narrowly understood, to form unions. People who act bravely against short-term interests might change this condition, to make it so that unionization becomes more in keeping with people’s short-term narrow interests. This is basically what happened in the 1930s. It may be happening again, or may be coming in the near future.
If all of this is happening or begins to happen soon, we should welcome it but also ask: yes, revive the strike, but for what purpose? To put it another way, let’s say the unions “revive the strike,” as Burns has called for. Then what? What Burns argues is that this could lead to greater unionization. Is that what we want? Should we measure success by rising rates of unionization, and in dollars and cents won on the shop floor?
We’re a revolutionary union. In my view, we should have an organizationwide conversation about different ways to organize a post-revolutionary society, what we think a revolution would look like in the countries where we operate and what activities might move a revolution closer. I’m not convinced that a militant labor struggle alone moves the working class toward a new society. What I’ve been calling venture syndicalism might be an effort by the labor movement to revive the strike in order use it to advocate for a new and “better” capitalism. We shouldn’t think that the militancy of a strike alone is a measure of how much it brings us closer to a new society.
More to the point, if we see the AFL-CIO and Change to Win labor groups begin to aggressively break the rules of labor law, we should welcome this, but will it change our understanding of those unions? If this happens we may be asked to stand with their struggles, and we should do so. But we should do so in ways that put us in contact with the members of those organizations, not primarily their staff and officers, and that will create conversations about what a good society would look like, not simply to address the issues of winning the short-term struggle. Otherwise we’ll be little more than unpaid volunteers in the venture syndicalist project..
Originally appeared in Industrial Worker (June 2013)
Comments
Decent piece. If I may, let me just suggest calling it "Venture Unionism...." I believe I catch why you're using the term syndicalism, as the mainstream is trying to use more syndicalistic forms. A sorta cover for their still fundamentally conservative business unionism. I just think that the term "syndicalism", outside "our" circles is somewhat confusing. FWIW, the old WSA tried to steer clear of using the term in public materials. Cause english speaking folks would generally be clueless as to what it means. Something like, "Oh. a syndicate, like the mob?" Or some such silly thing or it all.
I also like the piece. It's very good and important to make connections and build relationships with the new rank and file (if indeed this experiment yields results, which is anything but assured). But to what end? Certainly discussing life after capitalism is worthy, but strategically I think the emphasis ought to be on the question of what the labor movement should look like and what its relationship to the other social movements of the working class should be. I believe in being open about one's revolutionary politics, but the labor movement is at such a backwards, bureaucratic and (in many cases) reactionary state that I think the best worker insurgency we could hope for at this stage is one within (and to a great extent, against) the existing business unions, in favor of a new workers' movement free of so much of the old, godawful baggage that plagues us. If venture syndicalism gives the labor movement a fresh dose of young members, that's a great opportunity for a shake-up.
Second part to this column, here: http://libcom.org/blog/venture-syndicalism-fanning-dousing-flames-discontent-27072013
First time I came across this first part as well. Don't know how I missed it the first time around. That said, I have to agree with Syndicalist, I think venture unionism would be a better term. It has a much stronger suggestion of the trade unionism of the AFL-CIO than the syndicalism of the IWW.
Chilli Sauce
That said, I have to agree with Syndicalist, I think venture unionism would be a better term. It has a much stronger suggestion of the trade unionism of the AFL-CIO than the syndicalism of the IWW.
Agreed, especially in the US where syndicalism roughly translates to revolutionary syndicalism which translates to the IWW which translates to most on the left as "anarcho-syndicalism"
As I understand it "venture syndicalism" was meant in reference to the quasi-syndicalistic tendencies as syndicalist (hah) indicated.
the best worker insurgency we could hope for at this stage is one within (and to a great extent, against) the existing business unions, in favor of a new workers' movement free of so much of the old, godawful baggage that plagues us. If venture syndicalism gives the labor movement a fresh dose of young members, that's a great opportunity for a shake-up.
The "venture syndicalist" thing is about new organizing... meaning workers who weren't previously unionized. I really think rev-unionists have a weird instict of setting themselves up to lose, like in the bizarre mentality of "we could dual-card in the new fast food unions" type of thinking. Personally I think we should actively compete with the business unions, especially in unorganized industries (espec fast food).
As a side note, lots of wobs and similar minded folks have thought for awhile that fast food was the prime organizing turf because the business unions don't organize there, basically replicating the model of IWW as the union for rejects who the bigger unions don't organize. And now that the business unions are starting to organize there (big shock), folks seem a bit stumped. Which I find a little weird, personally. And a weird kind of taking credit attitude ("they're just copying us!") as if that means anything or changes anything.
I agree with KS above. Since I dont work in fast food and won't for some time I never started any efforts here in Chicago. But it was always a priority and I tried to get other IWW's to focus on organizing in this industry. Fortunately I feel the Fight for 15 efforts here are very broad and mass-based, with the organizing core relatively new to the game. Of course the SEIU funded and developed many of the organizers but there are many wildcards, different cities have autonomous committees etc...
I would like to see an effort to educate workers striking for better wages about the pitfalls of business unions, and a push towards more IWW positions (Forget living wage ordinances, Direct action gets the goods, Union on Our Own Terms, Revolutionary Industrial Organization). I feel there is a real opportunity to not only gather dual carders, but to possibly transfer this venture unionist project into the folds of the competition er OBU.
Comments