Return of the crisis: Part 2 - the nature and significance of the crisis

The second part of Aufheben's analysis of the financial crisis.

Submitted by Joseph Kay on October 30, 2011

Introduction

In Part I we gave an account of the immediately apparent causes and unfolding of the recent financial crisis, which began with the ‘credit crunch’ in the summer of 2007 and which culminated with near meltdown of the global financial system following the collapse of Lehman Brothers in the autumn of 2008. Here, in Part II of our article, we step back to consider the nature and significance of this crisis by looking at its deeper and longer term causes.

As we pointed out in the introduction to Part I, the recent financial crisis has brought forth a plethora of ‘radical theories’ purporting to explain the underlying causes of the recent crisis – mostly drawn from Marxism, but also from the more radical interpretations of the writings of John Maynard Keynes.1 Although these theories have many differences, and often come to distinctly different political conclusions, with a few notable exceptions, they have much in common. Firstly, nearly all of these ‘radical theories’ are essentially the same as those developed to explain the economic crises of the 1970s and 1980s. Secondly, most of these ‘radical theories’ can be described as being ‘stagnationist’: that is they are based on the proposition that capitalism is now in decline, and its underlying tendency is towards economic stagnation.2

During the 1970s and 1980s, when the advanced capitalist economies of North America, Western Europe and Japan were all being afflicted by slow economic growth, rising unemployment and high rates of inflation – a predicament that came to be known as stagflation – the proposition that capitalism had run into an impasse seemed almost self-evident; and certainly enjoyed a wide currency even amongst most bourgeois commentators and policy makers. The main contentious issue had then been how the underlying problem of economic stagnation could be resolved.

However, from the early 1990s there appeared to be a revival of capitalism with the beginning of what was to become a long economic upswing. The response of most ‘radical theorists’ was to argue that such a revival could only be short lived. Capitalism, it was argued, could now only provide a patina of prosperity on the basis of unsustainable debt and financial speculation. Sooner or later there would be an almighty financial crisis, the bubble of illusory prosperity would burst, and the underlying tendency towards economic stagnation would once again reassert itself. As a consequence, over the last twenty years the onset of any financial crisis of any significance has sent Marxists and radical Keynesians scuttling to their attics to bring down their ‘falling rate of profit machines’, ‘deficient effective demand detectors’ or other theoretical paraphernalia to demonstrate that this time the bubble had truly burst. Then, after each financial crisis had past and capitalism had resumed its upward path, they were obliged to put everything back into their boxes and sullenly take them back upstairs. As a result, with each successive financial crisis, the arguments of stagnationists had become less and less plausible.

The failure to account for the continuation of the economic upswing prompted some more critical Marxists, including ourselves in Aufheben, to question the received ‘stagnationist’ orthodoxy. This has led to the emergence a distinct heterodox current within Marxism that has argued that that the revival of capitalism was far from being illusory. Against the ‘stagnationists’, the ‘upswing’ theorists pointed out, the crises and restructuring of the 1970s and 1980s had succeeded in providing the basis for renewed capital accumulation.3 The decisive defeat of the working class in the USA and other advanced capitalist economies, the development of the ‘new economy’ of information and communication technologies and, above all, the integration of China and south-east Asia, with its vast reserves of cheap and acquiescent labour, into the US-centred global accumulation of capital had all served to bring about and sustain the long economic upswing since the early 1990s. As a result, by most measures profit rates returned to levels not seen since the long post war boom, there was steady economic growth, inflation was more or less conquered and unemployment had fallen.

Yet the financial crisis of 2007-8, which has plunged the world into the worst recession since the second world war, would seem to have turned the tables in the polemics between the ‘upswingers’ and the ‘stagnationists’. Although the ‘stagnationist’ theorists were still unable to provide a satisfactory explanation for the prolonged economic upswing, they could now claim to have been at long last vindicated – the almighty financial crash had, if rather belatedly, happened. The long upswing theorists, in contrast, now faced the problem of finding a convincing explanation for the financial crisis.
Given the problems of existing radical - and in particular Marxist - theories of the crisis, how are we to understand the nature and significance of the financial crisis and the current economic recession? Where should we begin looking for its underlying causes?

A major theoretical problem that we face is that although Marx provides us with perhaps the most incisive insights in understanding the crisis ridden nature of capitalism, he left no ‘unified general theory of crises’. Hence there has arisen a whole range of often conflicting Marxist theories of crisis, each one claiming support from particular passages in Marx’s ‘economic’ works. Yet even if we had an abstract ‘unified general theory of crisis’ it could only take us so far. Crises are by their nature historically specific. They are part of an open historical process in which the contradictions of capital’s development are brought to the fore and are forcibly resolved through class conflict. The resolution of one crisis then serves as the basis of the subsequent crisis. Each crisis has therefore to be understood in terms of the concrete historical circumstances out of which they arise. They cannot be simply explained a priori by some abstract schemas or formulae.

The basic problem of ‘radical theories’ of the current crisis, and this includes the ‘upswing’ theorists, is that they are still rooted in the analysis of the economic crises of 1970s. Of course there had been a number of financial crises in the 1970s, but these had been largely secondary if not rather peripheral to the fundamental problems afflicting capitalism at the time. After all it had been the sharp rise in the price of oil that had triggered the economic recessions of the 1970s not financial crises. As Marxists at the time had argued, these oil shocks had exacerbated the underlying economic and social problems caused by such underlying factors as the falling rate of profit, the increasing monopolisation of the economy and, of course, the breakdown of the post war class settlement and the consequent upsurge in working class militancy. As consequence, the financial system could be seen as little more than a parasitical excrescence on the real economy.

Yet, the recent crisis was first and foremost a financial crisis. After all, it was the crisis in the global financial system that can be seen as the cause of the subsequent world economic crisis. But neither the ‘stagnationists’ nor the ‘upswingers’ have developed an adequate theory of the development of global banking and finance over the past thirty years and have therefore been unable to provide an adequate explanation of the crisis.4

Of course, it is true that ‘stagnationist theorists’, particularly the radical Keynesians, have placed particular emphasis on the development of global finance and banking. In their polemics against the mainstream neoliberal economic theories of the role of finance and banking, they have certainly provided a powerful moral critique of the impact of the development of global banking and finance, by showing how it has both depressed the living standards of the working class and poor across the globe and caused havoc and economic instability. But in doing so they fail to grasp the positive role the emergence of global banking and finance has played in bring about the restructuring of capital accumulation and the rejuvenation of capitalism. Indeed, by retaining the conception of finance as a parasitical excrescence on the real economy, the ‘stagnationist’ theory of the emergence of global banking and finance, particularly in its more Marxist versions, has simply served to explain away the long economic upswing. As a consequence, their theory of finance has been rather ad hoc and one-sided.

On the other hand, in their polemics with the ‘stagnationists’, ‘upswingers’ have sought to emphasise the ‘economic fundamentals’ of the real economy - such as the restoration of the general rate of profit - that can be seen to have underpinned the long economic upswing. As a result the ‘upswingers’, including ourselves, have tended to overlook the importance of the rise of global finance and banking – and were thereby caught completely by surprise by the onset of the financial crisis.

In order to overcome the limitations of both the ‘stagnationist’ and ‘upswinger’ theories of the crisis we shall argue that it is necessary to consider far more closely the relation between the emergence and development of global banking and finance and the global restructuring of real capital accumulation that has occurred over the past thirty years. We shall argue that the emergence of global banking and finance has played a central role in the restructuring of global capital accumulation that brought about the long economic upswing. We shall then show how the continued development of economic restructuring of the real accumulation of capital over the past decade sowed the seeds for the crisis at the very heart of the global banking system.

Explaining the current crisis

On the eve of the crisis – the view from the cockpit
As we pointed out in some detail in part I of this article, on the eve of the current economic and financial crisis the masters of the universe, the plutocrats, their ministers and their minions could take a rather sanguine view of their world. Whatever political problems there may have been on the periphery with ‘Islamic terrorism’ and rogue states, the global capitalist system as a whole seemed to be in rude health. Although there were concerns at the growth of class conflict in China and elsewhere in Asia, and the European working class remained entrenched and resistant to ‘pro-market policies, for the most part social peace reigned.

The problems of stagflation that had beleaguered the previous generation of bourgeois policy makers had been overcome. Although it was considered important to maintain due vigilance, it could certainly be said that inflation had by and large been subdued. But more importantly the US had experienced more than fifteen years of, if not spectacular then certainly steady economic growth, which had only been briefly interrupted by the relatively mild economic downturn that had followed the dot.com crash. What was more, the first years of the new century had seen a broadening of world economic growth and prosperity. Newly ‘emerging market economies’ of less developed regions of the world, particularly Asia and Latin America, were now sustaining exceptionally high rates of economic growth; Japan had at long last begun to recover from its ‘lost decade’ of economic stagnation of the 1990s, the laggard economies of western Europe were at last beginning to pick up speed, and even Africa - the long forgotten continent – was showing signs of economic development for the first time in more than two decades.

Most bourgeois policy makers and commentators now accepted that the ‘tough and difficult decisions’ that had been taken to introduce neo-liberal policies had been necessary to lay the basis of the current era of economic prosperity. By helping to tear down the walls of ‘socialism’, protectionism and the national Keynesian economy, neo-liberalism had aided the birth of a new, reinvigorated global capitalism.

Of course, it could now be conceded, as the critics of neo-liberalism and ‘globalisation’ had vociferously pointed out at the time, that the immediate impact of unleashing ‘global market forces’ had produced an era of economic and financial turbulence that had often had a devastating economic impact - an impact that was largely borne by sections of the working class and the poor across the globe. Most of the advanced capitalist economies had been hit by the major economic recessions of the early 1980s and early 1990s. Russia and many of the eastern European countries had taken more than a decade to recover from the economic trauma of the neo-liberal ‘shock therapies’ imposed after the break up of the former Eastern Bloc. The 1990s had seen economic devastation caused by recurrent financial crises in Latin America and east Asia. Meanwhile, the 1980s and 1990s had seen the poorest countries, particularly those in sub-Saharan Africa, continue to groan under the onerous weight of debt inherited from previous decades.

Indeed, at the time, for many critics of neo-liberalism and ‘globalisation’ the dot.com crash in 2001 had heralded the culmination of the financial and economic turbulence of the 1980s and 1990s. The financial crises that had swept around the less developed parts of the global economy to such devastating effect had now returned home. It was thought that, with the bursting of the dot.com bubble, the US, the very heart of global capitalism, which through institutions such as the IMF and the World Bank had ensured that it had gained from the booms and busts elsewhere in the world, would finally obtain its comeuppance and would itself be plunged into a deep economic recession.

But, as the apologists for ‘globalisation’ and neo-liberalism could now point out, such predictions had been proved wrong. The bursting of the dot.com bubble, which saw $5 trillion wiped off the nominal value of shares of dot.com companies in the space of just six months, had certainly been a major shock to US-centred global financial system, and had threatened to bring about a severe economic recession in its wake. However, prompt action by the Federal Reserve Board and other central banks in cutting interest rates, combined with Keynesian-style cuts in taxes and expansion of public spending, had proved sufficient to minimise the impact of the dot.com crash. The financial system as a whole remained intact, while the consequent economic recession had proved to be mild and relatively short lived. Indeed, it could be argued that what the dot.com crash had served to demonstrate was the remarkable robustness and resilience of the global capitalist system.

Furthermore, by the spring of 2007 the dot.com crash could be seen as having brought to an end the era of financial and economic turbulence. There was talk amongst bourgeois commentators that the world economy had entered an era that future economic historians may well describe as the ‘great moderation’: an era of steady broadly based economic growth, low inflation and stable and orderly financial markets.

As such, for the apologists of neo-liberalism and global capitalism, the era of economic and financial turbulence of the 1980s and 1990s could be seen as merely the necessary birth pangs of a born again global capitalism that was now driving an ever expanding global prosperity in to the foreseeable future.

Prospects of the long upswing on the eve of the crisis
What bourgeois commentators viewed as the ‘great moderation’ was no patina of prosperity, which somehow simply hid the underlying tendency of modern capitalism towards stagnation. On the contrary, it was a view that was well-founded. The decisive defeat of organised labour in the advanced capitalist economies in the 1980s, combined by the rise of the ‘new economy’ and the integration of the vast armies of cheap and compliant labour in Asia into the world economy in the 1990s, had succeeded in bringing about a major restructuring of worldwide capital accumulation and, with this, a rejuvenation of capitalism. It has been the success of this fundamental restructuring of world capitalism that has led to the restoration of the rate of profit to levels not seen since the long post war boom, and these high rates of profit have consequently underpinned the long economic upswing that took off in the early 1990s and was only brought to an abrupt halt following the credit crunch of 2007.

Of course, against the triumphalism of the neo-liberal apologists of ‘globalisation’, it could be argued that the long upswing would sooner or later come to an end. The continuation of the long upswing had become increasingly dependent on the rapid rise of China as the distinct Asian epicentre in the US-centred global accumulation of capital. But the continued rapid accumulation of capital in China could not be taken for granted. Firstly, the rise of China had depended on its ability to provide a plentiful supply of cheap and compliant labour. Already by 2005 there had been signs that the demand for labour was in places beginning to run ahead of supply leading to a shift in the balance of power between workers and employers. After more than a decade of being static or even falling, there was growing evidence that wage rates in China had begun to rise. Secondly, the rapid economic growth of China had meant that world demand for food, fuel and raw materials was outrunning supply. The consequent rise in the price of food, fuel and raw materials not only threatened to squeeze profits in China but also, by causing an economic slowdown in the US and the west, led to a slowdown in the demand for Chinese exports, thereby curtailing the dynamic of China’s export led growth. Thirdly, China’s rapid and sustained economic growth had been dependent on state-directed investment and the insulation of the Chinese financial system from the volatility of global financial flows. With the Chinese authorities under increasing pressure from the US to open up its financial system, China could find itself going the same way as the Asian tigers of the 1990s. Foreign speculative investment could flood in, in an effort to take advantage of China’s vast surplus profits, and a speculative boom would result ending in an almighty crash.

Even if China managed to avoid such pitfalls and maintain its rapid accumulation of capital and economic growth, the long upswing in the US-centred global accumulation of capital would ultimately be limited. The rise of China had been able to sustain the long upswing because it had been based on a complimentary dynamic of accumulation with the US and other advanced capitalist economies. China, and behind it the rest of east Asia, has come to specialise in the production of cheap commodities that the US, and the other advanced capitalist economies, had either given up producing in the restructuring of the 1980s - such as textiles and clothing - or that they had never produced in the first place - such as computers, electronic toys and other digital and IT hardware. As such Chinese and Asian production did not overlap to any great extent with that in the west. Capital accumulation in China and Asia was therefore largely complimentary with that of the US and the western economies, allowing for a mutually reinforcing dynamic of capital accumulation between the west and Asia.

However, this complimentary dynamic of accumulation could be seen to hold within it the seeds of its own demise. Competition would inevitably reduce the world prices of Asian produced commodities to Chinese costs of production. As a result the surplus profits of Chinese producers would be eroded and the average rate of profit in China would tend to fall towards the world average.

However, so far this tendency towards a falling rate of profit in China has been limited by the active intervention by the Chinese state to restrict overinvestment. What is more, to the extent that this tendency has operated, it has been largely offset by Chinese producers moving into new but similar lines of production, for example by producing the latest, and more expensive, gadgets and gizmos. Yet, it can be argued, that the ability of China to limit or offset the falling prices and profits cannot be sustained forever. China will sooner or later have to move into the production of more sophisticated commodities, such as cars or machine tools. As a result its output will increasingly come into competition with that produced in the US and the other advanced capitalist economies. The largely harmonious dynamic of accumulation between China and the West will then give way to an increasingly competitive and potentially antagonistic zero sum game. It will be then that China will be obliged to challenge the US and make its bid for world economic hegemony, with perhaps dire consequences in terms of economic and military conflict.

But in 2007 the limits to the continued rise of China, and with it the rest of Asia, were only possibilities that were only beginning to loom on the distant horizon. In the short term the rise of China and the long upswing, which it was serving to sustain, seemed set to continue for at least another decade or so. Hence, for the time being the bourgeoisie and their minions rather sanguine view of the world could be seen as being more or less well-founded - even if it might prove to be more transitory than they would like to believe.

Conceptions of the significance and nature of crisis
As we pointed out in Part I of this article, by the spring of 2007 the mounting number of defaults on sub-prime mortgages in America had begun to be of some concern to the US monetary authorities. However, while the losses that the financial system was likely to suffer could be quite substantial and required monitoring, it had been assumed that the system would be robust enough to withstand the impact of such losses without too much trouble.

Few, if anyone, at the time foresaw that the collapse of the US sub-prime mortgage market would trigger a series of events that in less than eighteen months would lead to the near meltdown of the entire global financial system and as a consequence threaten the world economy with a great depression comparable with that of the 1930s. Even those Keynesian and Marxist critics who had argued that the housing bubble simply served to disguise the underlying tendency towards economic stagnation had failed to predict that it would end in such a severe financial crisis. For them the deflation of the housing bubble had been expected to lead to a decline in consumption, as homeowners could not borrow against rising house prices, and hence to a slowdown in the rate of economic growth in the economy, or perhaps even an economic recession.

But this brings us to the crucial question: if global capitalism was in the middle of a long upswing, with historically high rates of profits, how are we to explain the unforeseen financial crisis of 2007-08?

Most mainstream bourgeois commentators start with what would appear as the obvious fact that the current economic downturn was caused first and foremost by a financial crisis. It was the implosion of the financial sector, which had been triggered by the bursting of the US sub-prime mortgage market, which by impacting on what was otherwise a ‘fundamentally sound real economy’, has been the cause of the current ‘great recession’. As such there would seem to be little need to go beyond what can be seen as the immediate causes of the malfunctioning of the financial system, most of which could be seen as the result of policy errors on the part of governments or the monetary authorities.
Thus, as chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, Alan Greenspan can be blamed for holding interest too low and for too long in order to cushion the impact of the dot.com crash. This, it can be argued provided the conditions for the plentiful supply of cheap and easy money that fuelled the housing bubble. The bursting of the sub-prime mortgage bubble can then be seen to be a delayed consequence of Greenspan’s decision to belatedly restore interest rates to more normal levels after 2005.

But although ‘errors’ on interest rate policy might go some considerable way to explaining what fuelled the housing bubble, and why it burst when it did, it is perhaps insufficient to explain how it was possible for rising defaults in one small corner of the American mortgage market to result in the near meltdown of the global financial system. Why was it that a financial system that had been supposedly so robust proved to be so fragile?

From the wilderness, Keynesians had long warned that the neoliberal policy of gradually dismantling the structure of regulation and supervision of the financial system that had been originally put in place after the Wall Street Crash of 1929 would sooner or later end in tears. Following the credit crunch of 2007, these warnings appear to have been vindicated and are now taken far more seriously by mainstream bourgeois opinion. Even the least chastened ‘masters of the universe’ are now obliged to admit, the process of de-regulation and liberalisation of financial markets and institutions had gone too far. The only issue being how far is too far, and hence how much re-regulation is required.5

The notion that the financial crisis was the result of a combination of excessive financial deregulation and low interest rates certainly provides a starting point for an understanding of the immediate causes of the crisis. Of course, it is a notion sufficiently broad to encompass various interpretations and political conclusions. It surely supports the mainstream bourgeois view that has emerged in the wake of the crisis that with minor adjustments to financial regulation and a more prudent monetary policy there can be a return to business as usual.6 Alternatively it may also support the view of more radical Keynesians that such misguided policy is the inevitable result of dominance of neoliberal ideology over the formulation of monetary, financial and economic policy that has been established over the past thirty years.

However, on closer inspection this notion that the financial crisis was the result of ‘policy errors’ has a number of loose ends. Firstly, the process of financial regulation has been going on for more than three decades. Why had this deregulation made the global financial system so fragile in 2007 when it had been sufficiently robust to whether the impact of the dot.com boom six years before? Was this because financial deregulation had passed some unidentified tipping point? Or was is it that low interest policy not only produced the housing bubble and bust that caused the shock that triggered the banking crisis, but also itself contributed to increasing the fragility of the financial system?

But emphasis on the interest rate policy of the monetary authorities has its own problems. As Alan Greenspan would no doubt protest, the ability of central banks to determine interest rates ruling in the economy is limited by the balance of supply and demand for loanable funds in the financial system. It is true that the monetary authorities can regulate the level of short term interests by means of ‘open market operations’, whereby central banks buy or sell short term government securities, and by setting the ‘discount rate’ at which they are prepared to lend to banks. Interest rates on debts and securities with longer maturities or with greater perceived risks are normally based on the short term rates set by the central bank. By raising or lowering its own discount rate, together with the short term rates on government securities, the central bank can normally raise or lower the entire structure of interest rates in the financial markets as a whole. But the central bank can only do this to the extent that the interest rates it seeks to establish are broadly in accordance with the overall balance of supply and demand in the ‘money’ and ‘capital’ markets.

Some of the more perceptive bourgeois commentators, economists and policy makers have long been concerned that international financial imbalances that have arisen since the late 1990s have given rise to what has become known as a ‘global savings glut’.7 This has led to a tendency towards an oversupply of loanable money capital in the world’s financial markets that has exerted downward pressure on interest rates.8 As such, it can be argued that it was not low interest rates that caused the flood of easy money and credit; but rather it was the flood of loanable money-capital that was the cause of lower interest rates.

Because of the emergence of a ‘global savings glut’, Alan Greenspan had been able to cut interest rates and sustain them at exceptionally low levels after the dot.com crash, despite a ballooning US government budget deficit that was greatly increasing the demand for loanable funds on the financial markets. However, when he sought to reverse his low interest policy in 2005, Alan Greenspan found that he was now working against the tide of the money and capital markets. The Federal Reserve Board succeed in more than doubling short term rates. However, longer term rates, weighed down by an oversupply of loanable funds, initially rose by far less than short term rates, and then began to fall back. As a result, between 2005 and 2007 there arose a flattening and even an inversion of the so called ‘yield curve’ – as the difference between short and long term interest rates became compressed, and at times even went negative.9

This inversion of the ‘yield curve’ can be seen to have given a further twist not only to the rapidly expanding housing bubble, but also to the increasing fragility of the financial system. Low interest rates had already reduced the profit margins that could be made on loans The commercial banks had responded by offsetting lower margins by increasing the volume of their loans – a sort of financial version of pile them high sell them cheap policy – seeking higher returns on more risky assets – that is known as ‘a search for yield’ - or move into investment banking by securitising its debt and selling it on, making profits from management fees and commissions rather than from interest payments. All of which can be seen to have been vital ingredients of the process that was to lead to the credit crunch of 2007 and the consequent financial crisis. The inversion of the yield curve following Greenspan’s decision to raise short term interest rates, meant that the profit margins of commercial banking operations, which depended on borrowing short term and lending long, became further squeezed, accelerating this process.

So, while monetary policy regarding interest rates might be blamed for accelerating developments that were to end in the big crunch, it was not the prime cause of the crisis. The prime cause can be traced back to the ‘global savings glut’ that had depressed interest rates and had produced an excess in the supply of loanable capital looking for profitable outlets such as the US mortgage market.

The view certainly goes beyond the notion that the credit crunch was merely a result of misguided policy. It also, as we shall see, serves as a point of departure in placing the crisis in a broader historical perspective. But, as far as it goes, this view still sees the crisis first and foremost as a financial crisis.

Now of course, from a Marxist perspective it may be argued that the sheer scale of the financial crisis, and its dramatic impact on the real economy, indicate that it was a manifestation of much deeper contradictions of global capitalism. After all did not Marx argue that the contradictions of capitalism burst ‘forth as monetary crisis’?10 Of course, it is from this conception of the financial crisis as being a symptom of deeper economic contradictions that has provided the entry point for the revival of the various radical Keynesian and Marxist stagnationist theories to explain the current crisis. Yet, the problem in resuscitating such theories to explain the financial crisis of 2007-8 is to find a plausible means of explaining away the long upswing of the past decade and half. If we reject the notion that the upswing was little more than an illusion, a patina of prosperity created by a series of asset bubbles that have now all gone pop, how do we explain the nature and significance of the crisis?

Of course the obvious logical way around this problem is to claim that the crisis reveals that, unbeknownst to anyone at the time, we have already passed a decisive turning point in the history of capitalism – the long upswing has in fact ended and we have now entered a long down swing of the Krondratiev cycle.

Yet there would seem to be little to suggest that we have entered a long down swing, other than the fact of the financial crisis itself. Indeed what evidence there is suggests the opposite, particularly for those who emphasise the determining role of the rate of profit. Although they have certainly been dented by the crisis, profit rates still remain at historically high levels in the US and elsewhere. Furthermore, although the levels of investment - and hence capital accumulation - fell sharply during the financial crisis, and still remain at subdued levels, what evidence there is suggests that what is holding back a recovery in investment is a lack of finance due to the continued retrenchment of the banks, rather than because of any lack of profitable opportunities for investment. Indeed perhaps what has been most remarkable about the current crisis has been the resilience and continued buoyancy of much of the ‘real economy’ despite the impact of the implosion of the financial system. Far from representing a critical turning point, the crisis at present appears far more as merely an interruption, or at most an inflexion point, in the continued ascent of the long upswing.

But this does not mean that the financial crisis was merely an accident, or the result of policy errors that have little or no necessary connection with the real accumulation of capital. On the contrary, we shall argue that the financial crisis must be grounded in the upswing itself.

The finance sector is neither an autonomous sphere independent of the ‘real economy’, nor is merely an expression of the real accumulation of capital. There is a complex inter-relation between the accumulation of moneyed capital and the accumulation of real capital. If we are to understand the underlying causes of the recent financial crisis we must consider the historical development of this complex inter-relation.

We shall begin by looking at the origins of the global financial system and the crisis of capital accumulation in the 1970s. We shall then consider the role the emergence of the global financial system played in the restructuring of capital accumulation and the restoration of profit rates in the 1980s and 1990s that was to provide the basis for the long upswing. Finally, we shall examine how further developments in restructuring of global capital accumulation since the late 1990s have given rise to the ‘global savings glut’, and with this the over expansion of global finance that resulted in both the ‘great moderation’ and its denouement in the current financial crisis.

The Rise of Global Finance

The post war boom and the repression of banking and finance
At least for the advanced capitalist economies of North America and Western Europe, the long post war boom of the 1950s and 60s – the ‘golden age of Keynesianism’ – had been a period of unprecedented economic growth, growing prosperity and social peace. At the time it had seemed that capitalism had at last been tamed. The violent booms and slumps that had afflicted much of the world in previous decades could now be considered a thing of the past. As the more radical Keynesians have emphasised, vital to this taming of capitalism had been the ‘repression of finance’ that had been established on the basis of the Bretton Woods agreement.

The Bretton Woods agreement is perhaps most famous for establishing the post war system of fixed exchange rates. In order to promote international trade the currencies of the major advanced capitalist economies were to be freely convertible, that is they could be freely exchanged with each other on the foreign currency markets. However, in order to prevent the competitive devaluation of currencies, which was widely seen to have severely exacerbated the world depression of the 1930s, it was agreed that all the governments party to the agreement, except that of the USA, should intervene in the foreign currency markets to maintain a fixed rate of exchange of their currency with the US dollar.

However, central to maintaining this fixed rate system had been the agreed right of governments to impose strict controls on the movement of money-capital across borders. These capital and exchange controls were designed to allow governments to prevent speculative flights of capital that might otherwise undermine their ability to defend the value of their currency.

By creating barriers to the international movement of money-capital, capital and exchange controls had severely restricted the development of international banking and finance. Most international monetary flows were closely tied to international trade. As such the international operations of banks and financial markets were confined to providing currency transactions necessary for the buying and selling of internationally traded ‘goods and services’, shipping insurance and credit to bridge lengthy shipping times.

Furthermore, what international capital flows there were mostly took the form of inter-governmental loans or direct foreign investment by transnational corporations. In either case banks and financial markets had played merely a secondary and supporting role. As a result the international flows of free loanable money-capital, not immediately tied to the current production and sale of commodities, was limited. International banking and finance remained in a rather embryonic form, confined to the cracks and crevices between the national jurisdictions of the monetary authorities.

With limited opportunities to take flight abroad, it was relatively easy for the monetary authorities in each of the advanced capitalist economies to domesticate financial capital. The highly restrictive regimes regulating banking and finance that had been put in place in the USA following the Wall Street Crash, and in western Europe due to the exigencies of resource planning during the war, were, for the most part, maintained.

The restrictions and compartmentalisation of banking meant that the primary role of banks became that of providing banking services and credit necessary for the efficient reproduction of industrial and commercial capital. As such, banks became regarded as little more than rather staid privately owned public utilities. Financial markets became dominated by institutional investors such as pension funds and insurance companies, which were charged with pooling and investing the savings of the middle and working classes. These institutional investors were primarily concerned with safe and steady long term investments, rather than with making a quick buck. These institutional investors therefore preferred to invest either in the shares of well established and dependable ‘blue chip’ companies or, more often than not, government securities issued to fund state borrowing.

The main players in determining capital accumulation were the large commercial and industrial monopoly corporations and conglomerates, which had come to dominate the advanced capitalist economies since the beginning of the twentieth century. Although it is true that these monopoly corporations had continued to raise capital through the issuing of shares or corporate bonds, for the most part their investment was financed through ‘retained earnings’ – i.e. out of their current or past profits.

Through the ‘repression of finance’ governments were able to ensure the financial and economic stability that was necessary to maintain the steady accumulation of real productive capital, and hence economic growth. Through the tight regulation of banking and finance governments were able to limit speculative bubbles that might otherwise disrupt capital accumulation in the real economy. Such constraints on finance also gave governments considerable freedom to use Keynesian monetary and fiscal policies to maintain a steady growth in effective demand conducive to large scale and long term investments carried out by the monopoly corporations. The monetary authorities were able to keep interest rates low in order to maximise ‘retained earnings’ and hence high levels of productive investment. At the same time, despite low interest rates, governments were able to borrow from the captive financial markets to fund the large scale public investments in the nation’s economic and social infrastructure necessary to support real capital accumulation.

As a result, banking and finance, in each of the advanced capitalist economies, was subordinated to the national accumulation of real productive capital. This ensured steady economic growth, rising profits and wages, near full employment, increased public services and the establishment of the welfare state central to sustaining the various post war class settlements and hence social peace.

The rise of international banking and finance
The 1970s saw a major transformation of international banking and finance that was to bring an end to the ‘repression of finance’. There were three main causes of this ‘liberation of finance’: first of all there was the collapse of the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates, secondly the recycling of ‘petrodollars’ following the ‘oil shock’ of 1973, and finally the rapid growth of ‘offshore banking’. Let us briefly consider each in turn.

As we have seen, in accordance with the Bretton Woods agreement, the governments of the advanced capitalist economies, other than the USA, had been obliged to maintain a fixed rate of exchange between their currency and the US dollar. The US government, for its part, had in turn agreed to fix the value of dollar to gold. To do this the US guaranteed to convert on demand dollars into gold at the rate of $35 for each ounce. At the time of the signing of the Bretton Woods agreement in 1944 this obligation to convert US dollars into gold at a fixed rate had been inconsequential for the US government’s economic and political policies. As a consequence of the war, Fort Knox held around three quarters of the world’s entire stock of gold. But more importantly, with much of Europe devastated by war, American industry faced little competition. As a result throughout the 1950s the US enjoyed a substantial trade surplus, as its exports flooded into Europe. This had led to a severe dollar shortage in western Europe. Foreigners, particularly Europeans, wanted US dollars, now the undisputed world currency, not gold.

However, with the recovery and reconstruction of western Europe and the rise of Japan, US industry faced increasing competition. The US trade surplus declined at the same time as foreign direct investment by US transnational corporations in Europe increased. By the 1960s the dollar shortage had begun to become a dollar glut. The threat that the overhang of surplus dollars held by foreign banks and governments might be presented for conversion into gold now began to place onerous constraints on the freedom of US economic and political policy. The arms race with the USSR, the escalation of the Vietnam War, together with the need to secure social peace at home through expensive social programmes such as President Johnson’s ‘Great Society’, required unprecedented levels of government spending. But such high levels of government spending only served to worsen the outflow of US dollars.

In 1971, in order to cut himself free of such constraints, President Nixon suspended the US government’s commitment to convert dollars into gold and unilaterally announced a 10% devaluation of the dollar. This precipitated the collapse of the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates. By 1973 attempts to shore up the system had been abandoned in favour of a system of managed floating exchange rates, in which governments only intervened in the foreign currency markets to limit excessive fluctuations in the value of their currencies.

The abandonment of fixed exchange rates opened up profitable opportunities for speculation in the day-to-day fluctuations of exchange rates on the foreign exchange markets. It also opened up profitable opportunities for banks to sell ‘financial products’ that would allow exporters and importers to hedge against adverse movements in the value of currencies. The collapse of Bretton Woods thereby certainly contributed to an increased internationalisation of the operations of the national banking and finance systems of the advanced capitalist economies.

But the collapse of the fixed exchange rate system did not immediately lead to an end to capital and exchange controls or the barriers separating the national banking and financial systems of the advanced capitalist economies. Far more important in this was the recycling of petrodollars, caused by the oil shock of 1973, and the consequent development of offshore banking.

In 1973 the world economy was rocked by OPEC quadrupling the price of oil. As a result of the sharp rise in oil prices, the low cost oil-producing sheikdoms of the Middle East suddenly found themselves awash with US dollars with little to spend it on other than yet more palaces and camels. As a consequence, they began depositing their surplus oil revenues in Eurodollar accounts of European banks and European subsidiaries of American banks, which had grown up to avoid US capital and exchange controls. These accounts were particularly attractive, not only because they offered high rates of return, but also because they were out of the reach of the US monetary authorities, and were therefore less likely to become impounded by the US government in the event of a political or diplomatic crisis. With the stream of ‘petrodollars’ flooding into their Eurodollar accounts the western banks, which operated within the Eurodollar system, now had to find somewhere to invest this money that could provide them with sufficiently high returns to cover the returns they offered on their Eurodollar deposit accounts. With the US and other advanced capitalist economies plunged into recession following the oil shock, the banks had to look beyond their traditional clientele of other banks and transnational corporations. As a result they began making large scale loans to ‘third world’ governments.

This recycling of ‘petrodollars’ brought about a dramatic expansion in both the scale and complexity of the international finance and banking system. Whereas previously it had been a rather marginal and arcane activity for the major US and other western commercial banks, international banking operations now became a substantial potential source of profits. As a consequence, banks rapidly expanded their international operations, bringing about a profusion of specialist international financial intermediaries, and the development of new ‘financial products’ and markets in order to facilitate the increased volume deals.

But this was not all. In order to expand their share of international banking and finance, the western banks began opening up subsidiaries that were nominally registered in small ‘third world’ states that offered both minimal taxes on financial transactions and lax banking regulations. The banks were then able to offer their domestic corporate and more well-heeled individual depositors the option of transferring their deposits to their ‘offshore’ subsidiaries. With economic and political uncertainty and falling returns in the US and western Europe, the risk of placing funds in minimally regulated banks was for many depositors more than offset by the higher returns such offshore banking offered - particularly as these banks had the implicit backing if things went wrong of their reputable parent banks.

Loanable money capital accumulated in the advanced capitalist economies could now flow into the channels of international finance that had been carved out by the recycling of petrodollars. The growth of offshore banking allowed the banks to evade regulatory controls that had inhibited the free movement of money-capital across national boundaries. In doing so offshore banking prised open the cracks in the national regulation of finance, weakening the walls that had been erected to separate the various national banking and financial systems from the largely unregulated and unconstrained international banking and finance.

As a result of the break up of the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates, the recycling of petrodollars and the development of offshore banking, the 1970s saw an explosive growth in international banking and finance. By the end of the 1970s the volume of international flows of loanable money capital had grown to such a scale that they threatened to overwhelm any attempt to control it on the part of governments and monetary authorities. In 1979 the levees began to break.

Firstly, in May 1979 Margaret Thatcher came to power committed to dismantling Keynesianism and the post war social democratic settlement in Britain. Under the slogan ‘you can’t buck the [financial] markets’, one of her first moves in this direction – the significance of which is often overlooked - was to scrap capital and exchange controls, allowing the free movement of money and capital in and out of the British economy. Within the next few years all the advanced capitalist economies had been obliged to follow Thatcher’s lead. As a consequence, the barriers to the free movement of capital across borders were torn down.

Secondly, in October 1979, Paul Volcker, the newly appointed chairman of the US Federal Reserve Board, announced a sharp about turn in US monetary policy. Following the second ‘oil shock’, which had seen a doubling of oil prices, there had been growing fears that the consequent increase in the US trade deficit could trigger an uncontrollable speculative flight of capital from the US and, with this, a collapse of the US dollar on the foreign exchange markets. In order to ward off such a threat Volcker abandoned the last vestige of Keynesian monetary policy of maintaining low interest rates. US interest rates were forced up leading to a huge influx of loanable money-capital into the USA and a soaring dollar. In order to limit the outflow of money-capital to the US, the other advanced capitalist economies were obliged to follow suit and raise their own interest rates and, in doing so adopt monetarist economic policies.

As such, 1979 marked the end of Keynesianism and the triumph of what was to become known as neoliberalism. Governments and monetary authorities gave up attempting to subordinate banking and finance to the national accumulation of real productive capital through restrictive regulations. The free movement of capital was now to be promoted. As barriers to the free movement of finance capital were progressively dismantled the national banking and financial systems became merely segments of what was to become a US-centred global banking and financial system, in which money-capital could freely flow in search of the highest returns.

The ‘liberation’ of finance and the stagnation of the ‘Fordist mode of accumulation’.
As radical Keynesians such as Susan Strange and Howard Watchel have pointed out, concerted action on the part of governments and monetary authorities could have perhaps prevented the explosion of international banking and finance. Thus, for example, following the rise in oil prices in 1973, there could have been an international agreement that would have allowed for petrodollars to be recycled through official intergovernmental channels, overseen by such bodies as the IMF and the World Bank. Furthermore, the monetary authorities in the US and elsewhere could have imposed new financial regulations to clamp down on the subsequent growth of offshore banking, and thereby nipped it in the bud.

For radical Keynesians, the lack of political will to take such action is seen, at least in part, as the result of the growing political influence of finance and banking over the formulation of economic policy. The economic crisis, which had for them been primarily caused by the sharp rise in the costs of oil, food and raw materials in the early 1970s, had led to a crisis in confidence in the continued efficacy of Keynesian policies. Taking advantage of this, banking and financial interests had been able to push towards the reversal of the ‘Keynesian revolution in economic policy’ and, with this, the progressive abandonment of the ‘repression of finance’.

Furthermore, as the radical Keynesians pointed out, the consequent rapid growth of international banking and finance in turn brought with it a corresponding increase in the political power and influence of the bankers and financiers. By the end of the 1970s they had reached a position where they could seize control over state policy. Keynesianism was deposed and replaced by neoliberalism. As a result, over the last thirty years economic policy across the world has been driven by the overriding special vested interests of bankers and financiers, much to the detriment of the rest of society, particularly the poor and the working class.

Many Marxists might well agree with radical Keynesians on this. However, for most Marxists, the sharp rise in the costs of oil, food and raw materials in the early 1970s had only served to exacerbate and bring to a head a much deeper crisis in the process of capital accumulation that had underpinned the long post war boom. As such the ‘crisis of Keynesianism’ had not been due to the transient problems of adjustment following the impact of the ‘oil shocks’ and rising ‘commodity prices’, but had been due the fact that capitalism had reached an impasse, which manifested itself in recurrent economic and political crises. There could therefore be no return to the ‘progressive capitalism’ of the ‘golden age of Keynesianism’.

As the Marxist French of the Regulation School, and many others have pointed out, the long post war boom had been driven by the rapid expansion of the mass assembly-line production of standardised consumer durables – epitomised of course by the production of ‘automobiles’ and known accordingly as the ‘Fordist mode of accumulation’. It may be admitted that Keynesian policy and the consequent ‘repression of finance’ had served a vital role in facilitating the large scale and long term investments in building and equipping the car factories, steel plants and petro-chemical complexes that had been necessary for the post war ‘Fordist’ economy. However, by the late 1960s these investments had begun to result in an over-accumulation of productive capital.

As a result there began a long term tendency for the general rate of profit to fall. Attempts to reverse the falling rate of profit faced formidable, if not insurmountable, problems.

Firstly, as we have seen, the large scale investments necessary for the rapid expansion of ‘Fordist’ mass production had been carried out by commercial and industrial monopoly corporations and conglomerates. As a consequence, these corporations had accumulated substantial amounts of fixed capital in the expansion of productive capacity. But by exploiting their monopoly position they were able to resist any scrapping of excess productive capacity and the devaluation of their fixed capital that this would entail. Thus there was little scope to remedy the over-accumulation through the scrapping of excess capital and the devaluation of accumulated capital.

Secondly, after nearly two decades of near full employment, the organised working class in the advanced capitalist economies had established strong entrenched positions that allowed them to thwart attempts to reverse the falling rate of profit through increasing the rate of exploitation. The ability of the working class to defend existing terms and conditions and working practices meant that attempts to increase the productivity of labour, through such means as raising the pace and intensity of production or through introducing new technology, had become increasingly limited.

Furthermore, attempts by capitalists to restore profits by raising prices only served to solicit demands for higher wages to compensate for the rising cost of living. This resulted in a price-wage spiral and thus accelerating inflation.
The falling rate of profit, coupled with the growing social instability and class conflict that it helped to exacerbate, resulted in a decline in productive investment and thus a slowdown in the real accumulation of productive capital. In order to offset this slowdown in capital accumulation and to maintain economic growth and full employment, governments sought to use Keynesian fiscal policies to ‘spend their way out of the crisis’. However, this merely aggravated inflation and put upward pressure on interest rates and led to mounting state debts.

Marxists could then argue that, in the face of falling rates of profit, economic stagnation and increasing political and social instability, the capitalists typical response to such problems was to take refuge in financial speculation. But banking and finance only served to redistribute not create surplus value. As such it was ultimately a zero sum game, in which capitalists sought to gain at the expense of other capitalists. Thus, the rise of the political and economic power of finance and the corresponding ideological turn to neoliberalism, could be seen as merely a symptom of the underlying stagnation of capitalism.

However, whatever the disagreements at the time between radical Keynesians and Marxists about the causes and significance of both the release of finance and the turn to neoliberalism, it could be agreed that it could only have a devastating economic and social impact, which seemed to offer little in the way of a long term to solution to the economic stagnation of capitalism. Indeed, following Volcker’s adoption of monetarist policies, the US, and consequently the rest of the world, was plunged into a deep recession. Manufacturing industry, in particular, was decimated, and unemployment soared to levels not seen since the Great Depression of the 1930s.

Although the decimation of industry served to eliminate excess productive capacity and thereby halt the fall in the rate of profit, at the time it seemed far from sufficient to resolve the problems of capitalism’s stagnation. Capital, it appeared, had nowhere to go after the ‘Fordist mode of accumulation’. The computer, information and communication technologies, which were to provide the basis of what was to become known as the ‘new economy’, were still in their infancy. At the same time, the concentration of Fordist capital accumulation in the advanced capitalist economies during the post war era had left much of the rest of the world undeveloped and lacking the economic infrastructure that would enable a large scale relocation of capital.

The recovery from the recession of the 1980s was only brought about by Ronald Reagan’s adoption of an economic policy that has often been described as being ‘military Keynesianism’. Following his election in 1980, Reagan abandoned the policy of detente and set about accelerating the arms race with the USSR. Military spending rocketed at the same time as Reagan slashed taxes on the rich and large corporations. As a result the US government budget deficit soared from 2.7% in 1980 to 6% of GDP in 1984. This quasi-Keynesian deficit spending provided a huge stimulus to the US economy allowing it to pull the rest of the world economy out of recession.

However, at the time, this appeared as merely a short term palliative to the underlying problem of economic stagnation. It could be persuasively argued that the US could not sustain such high deficits, particularly when the money that was being borrowed was being economically wasted on unproductive militarily expenditure and increased conspicuous consumption for the rich. It could be concluded with - what has become a repeated refrain amongst both Marxists and radical Keynesians up until the present day - that the economic recovery was based on an unsustainable bubble of debt.

This argument seemed to be confirmed with the return of the world economic recession at the beginning of the 1990s.
Meanwhile the sharp rise in interest rates and the economic recession at the beginning of the 1980s triggered the ‘third world’ sovereign debt crisis. This was followed by the biggest stock market crash in 1987 and the US Savings and Loans crisis of 1990. As such, the ‘liberation’ of finance and banking could be seen to have only served to increase economic and financial instability.

By the end of the 1980s many Marxists could argue that the restructuring of capital accumulation had largely failed. The only way out for capitalism was a cataclysmic event such as a world war that could bring about a mass destruction of capital and allow capital accumulation to take place on renewed footing. After all it could be argued that it had been the Second World War that had prepared the way for the long-post war boom. Yet with hindsight we can see how the basis for a new long upswing was already being put in place. We must now look a little closer at the role the emergence of global finance and banking had in this.

Global banking and finance and the foundations of the long upswing

The growth of international banking and finance meant that an increasing proportion of shares of the large monopoly corporations were being held by investors looking for the highest short term returns. Even a rumour that the next quarter’s profit forecast might prove disappointing could now lead to speculative flight from a company’s shares and a collapse in its share price. Such a fall in its stock market valuation could then put a company at risk of a hostile take-over bid.

As a result company managers were obliged to concentrate on the short term profit performance of the company in order to maintain high dividend payouts and keep the valuation of their company high. The ‘maximisation of shareholder value’ became an overriding imperative. Managers could no longer put off difficult decisions. They had to face down opposition from their workforce and push through rationalization, downsizing and outsourcing of ‘non-essential’ functions in order to make their companies mean and lean. Capital sunk in the company had to be sweated to earn the highest return. Failure to do so would mean being replaced by a new management team appointed by the new owners who would be ruthless enough to force through the necessary changes.

This competitive pressure exerted by the financial markets had two distinct effects. Firstly, it ensured that management kept wage rates down and work rates high in order to maximise profits. Secondly, by ensuring companies were ‘mean and lean’ it meant that any excess capital could be liquidated and siphoned off into the financial markets, in the form of higher dividend payments, to swell the pool of free loanable money-capital.

At first the growing pools of international loanable money-capital had ended up flooding into the USA to finance Reagan’s massive budget deficit. Although at the time it might seem the emerging global financial system was simply financing Reagan’s profligate tax cuts and military spending programmes, with hindsight it can seen that in doing so it was playing an important, if indirect, role in bringing about the restructuring of capital accumulation.

Firstly, the escalation of the arms race eventually brought about the fall of the ‘evil empire’ thereby opening up whole new regions of the world for capital accumulation in the following decades.

Secondly, and more immediately, the military programmes inaugurated by Reagan, particularly the Strategic Missile Defence Initiative or ‘Star Wars’ as it was commonly known, effectively served as a hidden state investment programme. Through Star Wars military spending was channelled into funding the vast research and development of the computer, information and communication technologies that was necessary to provide the foundation for the take off of the ‘new economy’ in the 1990s.

Under the Bush (Snr) and the Clinton administrations, concerted efforts were made to wind down the huge deficits that had been inherited from the Reagan era. By the end of Clinton’s second term the US budget deficit had been eliminated. However, by then whole new spheres of investment opportunities had opened up providing ample demand for the supplies of free loanable money-capital flowing through the global banking and financial system. Firstly there were the new emerging economies of Asia and secondly there was the emergence of the ‘new economy’.

Global finance and the ‘newly emerging market economies’
As we have previously mentioned, the long post war boom, driven by the ‘Fordist mode of capital accumulation’, had been largely confined to the USA and the other advanced capitalist economies. Most international capital investment had taken the form of foreign direct investment within the developed world – and was predominantly by US transnational corporations setting up production in Western Europe.

As a result, as third worldists at the time often lamented, much of the ‘third world’ was relegated to primarily producing raw materials and agricultural products, which lacked the economic dynamism provided by ‘Fordist’ manufacturing industries. As a consequence, capital accumulation in the core had only a minimal impact in promoting economic growth and development in the economies on the periphery of the western world.

There had, of course, been attempts by various ‘third world’ governments, often in alliance with the USSR and other state capitalist countries of the Eastern bloc, to pursue national autarchic industrialisation strategies. With varying degrees of success, governments in the periphery had sought to promote the development of domestic manufacturing industries by protecting the home market from manufactured imports. But by the 1970s these ‘import substitution’ strategies had largely run out of steam due to both limited home demand for manufacturers and by a lack of access to modern production technologies. Nevertheless, this limited development of manufacturing industries in the more developed ‘third world’ had created a substantial pool of cheap and compliant labour, which was both, accustomed to the disciplines of wage labour and possessed the necessary skills for factory production. Indeed, with much of the world population outside the heartlands of western capitalism there was, in the longer term, a vast potential for the global expansion of capital beyond the advanced capitalist economies.

However, there had been formidable barriers preventing western capital exploiting the vast potential pool of labour in the ‘third world’. Firstly there had been numerous political problems. Thus for example, any transnational corporation considering investment in a ‘third world’ country, particularly one that had been committed to a nationalist industrialisation strategy, faced the risk that the government might at some time in the future nationalise their investments.

But, perhaps more importantly, there were the sizeable economic barriers to the globalisation of capital. If transnational corporations were to set up production they first of all needed dependable communication and transport networks, and they needed reliable sources of power, gas and water, but the economies of the ‘South’ often lacked such basic economic infrastructure. Although there might be substantial savings in labour costs, given that labour in the ‘third world’ was far cheaper than that in the transnational corporation’s home country, this would usually be more than offset by the large scale investments required for the construction of the economic infrastructure necessary before production could even begin.

Secondly, the transfer of productive capital required the existence of an economic milieu of small- and medium-sized enterprises that could provide the vast range of ‘goods and services’ necessary to maintain day-to-day production and to feed, clothe and house the company’s workforce. In the absence of such local suppliers, a transnational corporation would have to ship everything required to maintain production itself. This would often not only have been prohibitively expensive, but also a logistical nightmare.

As a consequence, it had only been in agriculture and the extractive industries, such as mining, where climatic or geological factors meant there was no option but to site production in the less developed world, that the transnational corporations of the US and the western world had ventured south. Even then, as third worldists and development economists at the time often pointed out, foreign direct investment for the most part only created economically developed enclaves, since the transnational corporations only invested in economic infrastructure that was strictly necessary for their own operations.

In the 1970s the seeds were sown for what was to become the ‘globalisation of capital’, which was to see the outflanking of the entrenched positions of the working class in the advanced capitalist economies. And, as we shall see, the emergence of what was to become the global banking and financial system was to play a central part in the relocation of productive capital. First of all, in the face of falling profits, growing political instability and an increasingly intransigent working class in the heartlands of capitalism, transnational corporations began to look upon the prospect of relocating production, particularly manufacturing, to the more developed economies in the periphery far more favourably than they had previously. Secondly, there was the impact of the recycling of petrodollars through the emerging international banking system.

As the ‘sovereign debt crises’ of the early 1980s were to reveal all too clearly, much of the petrodollar loans made by banks to ‘third world’ governments had been frittered away either in fuelling local arms races or else on grand prestigious public projects that turned out to be white elephants. Nevertheless, a substantial amount of these loans had been used to promote a switch from an import substitution industrialisation strategy to an export-led strategy. Previously, any attempt to promote export-led growth had run into the problem of a lack of US dollars. Any large scale investment programme necessary to develop export industries would result in an initial surge in imports of raw materials and other commodities necessary to set up production. This would lead to a sharp rise in the outflow of US dollars to pay for them until production was up and running and the dollar revenues from export sales began to flow in. With limited dollar reserves a government attempting to promote such an investment programme would soon find itself with a serious currency crisis on its hands. However, with western banks falling over themselves to lend them petrodollars they had been able to lift this dollar constraint.

Furthermore, by borrowing from western banks ‘third world’ governments were able to finance the construction of the economic infrastructure necessary to encourage investment from western transnational corporations. This direct investment then brought with it access to both the most up to date production technology and to the transnational corporations well-established sales and distribution networks in their home markets.

Thus, the 1970s saw the beginnings of the relocation of the more labour intensive ‘Fordist’ lines of production to what were then known as the newly industrialising countries of the capitalist periphery. However, the world recession of the early 1980s saw a sharp fall in the demand for the manufactured exports from these countries. At the same time, as export revenues fell, the costs of servicing the huge debts that had built up rose with the sharp increase in interest rates. This produced the ‘third world’ sovereign debt crises of the early 1980s. With many western banks having had their fingers burnt in this crisis they became far less inclined to lend to ‘third world’ governments and the whole process of recycling petrodollars came to a halt.

Nevertheless, pressures on transnational corporations to exploit the opportunities that had been opened up to relocate production to the periphery were now to intensify. Firstly, the high exchange rate of the US dollar in the early 1980s, made many manufactured commodities produced in the USA uncompetitive. There was therefore a strong incentive for US transnationals corporations to continue to relocate production, particularly to nearby Central and South America. Then, with the sharp fall in the US dollar following the Plaza Agreement of 1985, and the corresponding sharp rise in the exchange rate of the Yen, many Japanese transnational corporations were prompted to transfer the more labour intensive stages of the production of commodities destined to be exported to the USA to neighbouring South Korea and Taiwan, whose currencies remained pegged to the US dollar and where there were plentiful supplies of cheap labour. As a result the momentum for the relocation of production was maintained through the 1980s.

As we have seen, by the late 1980s the US government had set about unwinding the huge budget deficits run up under Reagan. The demand for loanable funds to finance the deficit began to fall at the same time as the liquidation of capital in the old established Fordist industries of the US and other advanced capitalist economies continued to increase supply. As a result there was a renewed interest on the part of global banking and finance in what were to become known as the ‘newly emerging market economies’ of Asia and Latin America. Western banks began making loans not only to ‘third world’ governments and transnational corporations to facilitate the relocation of production, but also to local banks in Asia and Latin America. Using their local knowledge and business connections, these local banks were then able to make loans to a wide variety of small- and medium-sized firms crucial to developing the economic milieu of local suppliers that could then further encourage direct investment from transnational corporations and thereby hasten the accumulation of capital.

This dynamic process was given a further twist by Western banks securitising these loans and selling them on to other financial institutions interested in buying liquid assets that had offered high returns. This gave rise to what became known as the emerging market economies securities market that served to funnel short term investment flows into financing the rapid export led growth of Latin America and, in particular, east and south-east Asia.

Global finance and the emergence of the ‘The New Economy’
As we have seen, the dramatic increase in military spending under Reagan had, in part, served as a huge hidden state investment programme that had funded the rapid development of the new information, communications and computer technologies. State investment, driven by military objectives and imperatives, was central to startling advances both in the processing power and miniaturisation of hardware and the increasing sophistication of software, which was necessary in providing the foundations of what was to become the ‘new economy’. However, in the subsequent development of the commercial applications of these new technologies the role of private finance and investment was to play a far more significant role.

In the early 1990s it was still far from certain how the emerging new technologies would develop, how they would be used and how they could be made profitable. Investment in the emerging ‘new economy’ promised high returns but high risks. A situation well suited to ‘casino’ operations of high finance and banking. Banks were prepared to lavishly fund promising ‘new tech’ start ups and then float them on stock markets, selling shares to investors looking for high risk-high return investments. The flood of loanable money capital from banks and the financial markets then served to fuel the take off of the ‘new economy’ that occurred in the 1990s.

The take off of the ‘new economy’ had an important impact on the ‘old economy’, which in turn provided growing demand for ‘new tech’ products. Administration costs could be cut with the computerisation of offices, computer aided design reduced research and development costs, computerised stock control and faster and more efficient communications increased the turnover of capital and reduced amount of stocks that could be held, in these and in many other ways the commercial application of the new technologies served to increase the rate of profit in the ‘old economy’. Furthermore, the ‘new economy’ opened up a whole new range of commodities and ways of selling them from which profits could be made.

So, as we have seen, the emergence of global finance and banking played an important, but by no means an exclusive role, in the restructuring of world capital accumulation that provided the basis for the restoration of the general rate of profit and hence what was to become the long economic upswing.

First of all, the ‘liberation of finance’ helped galvanise capital to launch a counter-offensive against the working class at the level of both the state, through the implementation of neoliberal policies, and at the level of individual capitals, through rationalisation, redundancies and the intensification of labour. Secondly, the emergence of global banking and finance served to liquidate capital fixed in low profit industries, particularly in the old Fordist industries located with the advanced capitalist economies. And thirdly, by facilitating the transfer of this liquidated capital to potentially high profit locations and industries, the emergence of global banking and finance helped to open up new spheres of profits with the emergence of the ‘new economy’ and the ‘newly emerging market economies’ in Asia and elsewhere.

During, these early stages in the restructuring of global capital accumulation, particularly between the late 1980s and late 1990s, the demand from these new spheres of investment for free loanable money capital tended to outrun the supply. The period was characterized by a relative dearth of loanable money capital flowing through the global banking and financial system. An indication of this undersupply of money capital was the persistence of relatively high interest rates through this period. But perhaps more significantly it was reflected in the frequent specific financial crises that typify this time. As the limited amount of footloose loanable money capital swashed around from one specific area of investment to another it gave rise to booms and busts in each of these areas. Thus, for example, there was the savings & loans crisis in late 1980s, the Mexican crisis in 1994, the Asian crisis in 1997, the Russian crisis in 1998 and the dot.com crisis in the US stock market in 2001.

However, the restructuring of capital was to be taken to an altogether higher level with the rise of China. This opened up a new phase in the economic upswing that, as we shall now see, was typified by an oversupply of loanable money capital flowing through the global banking and financial system.

The Rise of China

In 1992 Deng announced a major shift in Chinese economic policy that was to prove to be of world historical significance. Abandoning more than forty years of autarchic economic development, China was to open its doors to large scale foreign investment. As a result foreign investment flooded in to China, rising from negligible levels in 1992 to more than $50bn (equal to 5% of China’s GDP) ten years later, driving China’s economic transformation into the new ‘workshop of the world’.

The Deng announcement certainly came at a propitious time. The economic boom of east and south-east Asia, which had begun in the late 1980s, was now in full swing. Attracted by cheap and compliant labour, foreign investment had flooded into Asia, first of all to the more developed countries such as Taiwan and South Korea and then, as labour shortages and wage rises began to take hold there, to what became known as the Asian tiger economies; the Philippines, Indonesia, Thailand, and Singapore. This incessant movement of capital in search of cheap labour had brought about both a disintegration and de-nationalisation of the production process in Asia. The production process of commodities was broken up into distinct stages; the more labour intensive stages being relocated to where there were lower wages and less skilled labour, while the more capital intensive stages were retained in those countries with relatively higher wages but a more skilled and reliable workforce. China, with its vast potential reservoirs of cheap and compliant labour, and its close proximity, appeared as an obvious next step for international investors. China could easily fit into the rapidly emerging Asian economy. Component parts produced across Asia could be transported for the more labour intensive stages of assembly in China before being shipped off to the US and western markets.

However, the Chinese state was determined not to fling open the doors for foreign investments and invite any fly by night investors or speculators in search of a quick return. Only foreign capitalists that were prepared to make long term investments directly in the development of real production were to be welcome. Typically such direct foreign investment was to take the form of joint ventures, co-owned by predominantly US transnational corporations and the Chinese state.

For their part the transnational corporations were to provide the design of manufactured products and advanced western technology embodied in plant and equipment necessary for their production. They were to provide business connections that could open the door to the distribution networks of the US and other western markets. And particularly important in the early stages of China’s integration into the US-centred global accumulation of capital, they were to provide working capital in the form of US dollars in order import the raw materials and other inputs necessary to get the joint venture off the ground. For its part the Chinese state was to provide a plentiful supply of cheap and compliant labour, along with investment in the economic infrastructure required for the efficient production and transportation of the commodities produced by the joint ventures.

Once the joint venture was up and running, the combination of western design and production technology, and a plentiful supply of cheap and compliant Chinese labour, certainly offered a win-win situation as far as the Chinese state and its ‘First-world chauvinist’ partners in their ‘imperialist citadels’. With costs of production far below any competitors elsewhere in the world, these joint ventures could sell well below the ruling world market price and still make handsome returns. The transnational corporation’s share of the joint venture’s profits would be sufficient to provide them with a rate of profit substantially higher than the general rate of profit they could expect to earn in the US or elsewhere in the advanced capitalist economies. But, at the same time, the Chinese state could ensure that it could appropriate the lion’s share of the returns in the form of taxation and its share of the joint venture’s profits, which could then be ploughed back in furthering capital accumulation and economic development in China.

In 1997 the economic boom in east and south-east Asia was brought to an abrupt halt. The rapid expansion of manufacturing industries had by the mid-1990s begun to outstrip the development of the economic infrastructure that was necessary to support it. Land and property prices had begun to rise sharply in the industrial and commercial areas of the region. The flows of short term foreign investment drawn from the western banks and the global financial markets, which, alongside direct foreign investment by transnational corporations, had originally helped finance the accumulation of real productive capital, now began to switch into property speculation. As a result, the rate of growth in manufacturing output, and with it Asian exports had begun to slow down. At the same time the windfall gains produced by the speculative property bubble to a large extent ended up being spent on luxury consumer imports. As a consequence, by 1997 the leading Asian tigers were heading for large and persistent trade deficits.

Nevertheless, it is possible that the trade deficits could have been sustained long enough to defuse the speculative boom if the Asian economies had been able to continue to attract enough US dollars in the form of foreign investment to cover the outflow of US dollars due to the trade deficit. But for the banks and financial markets the emerging ‘new economy’ in the US was now opening up safer if not more profitable investment opportunities for foreign investors, which now began to look like a better bet than carrying on investing in the Asian tigers in the hope that their economic imbalances could be sorted out without the bursting of the speculative bubble.

Pivotal to the Asian export-led boom had been the stability provided by fixed exchange rates, and it was with an exchange rate crisis that the wheels of the boom fell off. An essential ingredient to the success of the tiger economies had been the commitment of each of their governments to maintaining a given parity at which their national currency would exchange with the currency of both the world and their biggest export market - the US dollar. At the same time, with each currency pegged to the US dollar they were in effect pegged to each other creating an Asian system of fixed exchange rates.

During the height of the boom, when US dollars were flooding in, due to both high levels of foreign investment and rising revenues from export sales, this commitment had been easy. All the monetary authorities had to do was to buy up the surplus dollars with their own currency and deposit them in the nation’s foreign currency reserves. There was effectively no limit to preventing an appreciation of their currency against the dollar because they were always free to issue more of their own currency with which to buy dollars. Now, with a dollar drain, in order to defend a fixed exchange rate against the pressure towards the devaluation of their currency against the US dollar, they now had to be prepared to enter the foreign exchange markets and to buy up the surplus of their own currency with dollars, thereby depleting their dollar reserves. The monetary authorities were therefore limited by the amount of their reserves of dollar holdings.

Although the Asian tiger economies had together accumulated substantial reserves preventing their currencies appreciating against the US dollar during the height of the boom, it was now a depleting hoard divided up into several national reserves. It now became a plausible possibility that a well timed and sustained speculative attack on a currency of any one of the Asian tigers could be sufficient to exhaust that country’s national dollar reserves hoarded at its central bank, and force a sharp devaluation of its currency against the US dollar – thereby, of course, providing a killing for any speculator brave enough to lead the charge by betting early on such an outcome.

As it turned out, it was Thailand that proved to be the weak link and was the first to succumb to a speculative attack in July 1997. Tasting blood, the pack of currency speculators then turned on the Philipines. Within weeks the Asian system of fixed exchange rates had collapsed. Those foreign investors that could made for the exits. No longer able to borrow on the global financial market, Asian banks were no longer able to roll over their foreign debts and were forced to call in their loans to Asian businesses. Thus the exchange rate crisis rapidly developed into both a financial and economic crisis in the region, which was to see widespread bankruptcies, a sharp slow down in economic growth and tens of millions of workers plunged into abject poverty after losing their jobs.

At the time there had been serious concerns amongst Chinese policymakers that the shock waves from the financial and economic crisis elsewhere in Asia might wreck China’s still fledgling export-led growth strategy. However, with hindsight the Asian crisis provided a timely opportunity for China to establish itself as the hub of Asian manufacturing production. As we have seen, unlike its neighbours, China had avoided being reliant on the footloose short term investments provided by the western banks and the global financial markets. With its strict controls over capital flows and the convertibility of its currency, China was sheltered from the worst of the financial storm that was wreaking havoc elsewhere in the eastern Pacific. Amidst the economic chaos besetting its Asian neighbours, China now shone forth as a haven of stability. Overcoming any surviving misgivings that, as a still nominally Communist state, it might in the future revert to type and nationalise foreign investments, transnational corporations now focused their attention on China’s vast profit potential. Whereas the rest of the east and south-east Asian regions suffered a collapse in foreign investment in the aftermath of the crisis, China suffered merely a brief pause in its growth. China could now establish itself as the principal destination for foreign investment destined for the ‘newly emerging market economies’ of east and south-east Asia.

With foreign direct investment pouring in, and with the Chinese state ensuring approaching 50% of China’s GDP was reinvested, both in the expansion of export-manufacturing production directly, and in the state’s vast infrastructure construction programme that was necessary to sustain rapid economic development into the future, China had within less than five years established itself as the heart of the emerging Asian ‘tiger’ economy. At first this rise to prominence had at least been partly at the expense of its neighbouring ‘newly emerging market economies’ of east and south-east Asia. In the aftermath of the crisis, stages in the chain of manufacturing production, particularly the final assembly stages, previously undertaken elsewhere in Asia, were now relocated to China. Soon, most Asian manufactures destined for export to the US and other advanced capitalist economies, were at least partly produced in China. At the same time as establishing itself as the funnel through which Asian manufactures poured in the US and western markets, China began a concerted ‘move up the production chain’ to take on earlier more capital intensive stages of the production process. As a result China was able to secure a growing proportion of the value of the manufactured exports produced in the east and south-asian economy.

This displacement of value production from its Asian competitors was increasingly offset by two factors. Firstly, the rapid and sustained growth in the volume, and hence the total value, of Asian exports being funnelled through China to the US and the West increasingly compensated for the declining proportion of this total value falling to China’s neighbours. Their slice of the cake might be diminishing relative to that of China, but this could be largely offset by the growth in the total size of the cake. Secondly, China’s ambitious infrastructure construction programme – that was to see industrial cities the size of London being brought into being in a matter of few years – required huge quantities of oil, coal, timber, steel and concrete, along with various other raw materials, necessary to build road and rail networks, power plants and other utilities, as well as to construct houses, offices and factories. Before the Asian boom, many of the Asian tiger economies had specialised in the production of such raw materials. Hence it was relatively easy for them to revert back and expand such production to meet China’s growing demand.

By the early years of the new millennium, China had become not only the heart but the locomotive of the region. China’s economic growth was serving to pull it neighbours out of the recession that had followed the 1997 financial and economic crisis. However, China had not only established a complimentary dynamic of accumulation between itself and the ‘newly emerging market economies’ of east and south-east Asia. It had also, as we have previously mentioned, established a similar, and perhaps far more important, dynamic of accumulation with the USA.

The essential complementarity in the economic relation between the USA and China was certainly recognised and reflected in the rather sanguine view taken on the part of the US bourgeoisie to the rapid emergence of China as a major economic powerhouse in the world. Of course, there were concerns dating back to the early stages of the Asian boom in the 1980s, that the import of cheap Asian manufactured goods was displacing American industry and making American workers redundant. Now, with the rise of China, this stream of Asian imports had become a flood. But it could be countered that to the extent that imports from China were driving American industry out of business, this was for the most part only hastening the demise of those American industries that had long been in a state of decline anyway. What was more, a large proportion of the commodities now being imported from China was hardware for the information and communication technology that had not been previously produced in the USA in the first place because they had yet to be invented. Indeed, it is perhaps true that overall the displacement of American industry and jobs arising from Chinese competition has been marginal. Although, of course, the threat of outsourcing to China has proved a potent weapon in the armoury of the capitalist in keeping down the demands of the American working class in recent years.

There were plenty of other good reasons for the American bourgeoisie to welcome the rise of China. The flood of cheap manufacturers from China had played a valiant part in the defeat of inflation. The high returns from their joint ventures in China bolstered the profits of US transnational corporations and enhanced the dividends distributed to their large American shareholders. Not only this, as we shall see in more detail shortly, the Chinese monetary authorities could be said to have played a key role in allowing the US government and the Federal Reserve to take action to mitigate the economic downturn following the dot.com crash.

If this was not enough, it was the rise of China that had served to substantially broaden the US-centred global accumulation of capital. By the middle of the last decade, rapid Chinese economic growth had meant that world demand for fuel, raw materials and food was beginning to outrun supply. As a result, world prices for such ‘primary commodities’, which for nearly two decades had been depressed, began to rise. This was a boon for those economies that produced such commodities in the less developed world - not only in Asia, but now also in Latin America and even Africa - who could now export more at a better price. But it was not only economies on the periphery of world capitalism that benefited from the rapid economic growth in China. China’s growing demand for more sophisticated manufactures, such as machinery, machine tools and heavy vehicles, had begun to haul even Japan out of its long period of stagnation. The rise of China had served to raise the rate of accumulation across the globe, and in doing so could be seen as opening up plenty of investment opportunities.

Yet despite all this, there had certainly been worries amongst bourgeois commentators at the time concerning the sustainability of the growing ‘financial imbalances’ that had arisen along with the rise and continued expansion of China. To understand the relation of the rise of China to the financial crisis it is necessary to turn and consider these financial imbalances more closely.

The rise of China and the supply and demand of loanable money- capital
For the neoliberal ideologist China’s great economic transformation over the last two or three decades is due to China abandoning a ‘socialist command economy’ in favour of a ‘free market capitalism’. But, as we have seen, what has been essential to the continued rise of China has been its rejection of what is usually taken as the epitome of free market capitalism - the financial markets. China’s rapid capital accumulation has been financed first and foremost through state-directed investment. The Chinese state has ensured that the most of the surplus value produced in China has been reinvested in China. To the extent that Chinese capital accumulation has been dependent on external financing this has taken the form of foreign direct investment by transnational corporations, rather than by borrowing from western banks or issuing debt on the global financial markets.

As such the rise of China has had little direct impact on the demand for loanable money-capital in the global financial system. But it can be argued that it has served to increase the demand for loanable money-capital indirectly at least in two distinct ways. Firstly, in raising capital to invest in joint ventures in China, the transnational corporations will certainly themselves have resorted to the financial system by issuing shares and corporate bonds or else taking out bank loans. The long delivery times involved in producing in China and selling in the USA also require short term credit from banks or the financial markets. However, the bulk of the investment funds will have come from retained profits; at first largely from the profits made in the US and subsequently, increasingly from ploughing back profits previously made in China.

Secondly, and more indirectly, to the extent that it has stimulated capital accumulation elsewhere in the world, the rise of China can be seen to have increased the demand for loanable money-capital. This is perhaps particularly the case for those emerging market economies that, unlike China, have been more open to allowing an inflow of investment funds from western banks and the financial markets.

Yet overall, given its scale, the emergence of China as the Asian epi-centre of the global accumulation of capital has had a relatively limited impact on the demand for money-loanable capital from the global financial system. Yet this is not so much the case when we turn to consider the supply-side. To see this we have to look more closely at the ‘financial imbalances’ that have emerged between China and the US.

Trade and financial imbalances
As we have mentioned, an essential ingredient to the success of the Asian boom had been the commitment on the part of the governments of east and south-east Asia to maintaining a fixed exchange rate between their own currencies and the US dollar. However, this policy objective had not been merely confined to these Asian economies. Across the less developed world those economies seeking to follow the Asian example of export-led growth had, with varying degrees of success, attempted to tie the value of their currencies to that of the US dollar. The financial crises that hit Asia and Latin America during the 1990s had served to disrupt this tendency towards a system of fixed exchange rates amongst the ‘emerging market economies’. However, since then this tendency has resumed, with China emerging as the keystone in this new system of fixed exchange rates. This gave rise to some bourgeois economists to declare the emergence of a new Bretton Woods system of exchange rates.11

As China became the main portal through which cheap Asian manufactures were pouring into American markets, its trade surplus with the USA grew rapidly. But up until 2002 this had been more than offset by its trade deficit with east and south-east Asia. As such, the US dollars that came into China in the form of export revenues and foreign investment were spent on the purchase of component parts and other intermediary products necessary to produce the commodities bound for export to the USA, and the raw materials and products necessary to maintain its vast infrastructure construction programme. In 2002 China’s growing trade surplus with the USA overtook its Asian trade deficit. From then on China found itself with a growing surplus of dollars that placed upward pressure on the dollar value of the yuan. In order to maintain its fixed exchange the Chinese monetary authorities were obliged to buy up the surplus dollars. China’s foreign exchange reserves, which were largely made up of US dollars, soared. In little more than five years China’s monetary authorities had accumulated more than $2 trillion in its foreign exchange reserves.

However, the Chinese authorities, like all other monetary authorities facing a surplus of dollars, did not simply stuff their vaults full of greenbacks. The dollars were used to buy up US treasury bills. In this way the Chinese monetary authorities were able to ‘put their reserves to work’ earning a modest interest by investing in safe security that could easily be converted back into dollars in an emergency. At the same time, the dollars were recycled back to the USA, helping the US government to finance both its own debt and the American economy’s growing trade deficit with China.
This recycling of China’s dollar surplus proved to be quite timely since it allowed the USA to pursue the expansionary fiscal and monetary policies that were necessary to mitigate the financial and economic aftershock of the dot.com crash. Between 2002 and 2004 the US government had moved from a budget surplus amounting to more than 2% of US GDP to a 4% deficit as it cut taxes for the rich and increased spending to ward off a severe economic recession. With China’s growing appetite for US treasury bills, the US government found it relatively easy to finance this sharp increase in the government deficit without pushing up interest rates. Indeed, with the short term money markets swollen by the recycling of China’s dollar surplus, the US monetary authorities had been able to drastically cut interest rates.

Of course, by allowing the US to reflate its way out of recession, China was able to sustain its growing exports to the USA, and hence its export-led growth. This recycling of China’s dollar surplus certainly seemed to have ensured a mutually beneficial economic dynamic between the USA and China. However, there were certainly concerns expressed amongst bourgeois economists at the time over the sustainability of this dynamic, most of which focused on the problem of mounting US debt that this involved.

The US had been running a substantial trade deficit with the rest of the world for more than two decades. In order to cover this trade deficit it had been necessary that financial inflows into the US had grown faster than outflows. Indeed, as long ago as the late 1980s the US had turned from being the world’s largest creditor nation to being its largest debtor nation. As a result, by 2005 US debt accumulated by foreign corporations and governments amounted to more than 75% of the annual GDP of the USA. The issue was how much longer the USA could continue to borrow, particularly now that much of this borrowing was being used to finance unproductive government expenditure and a debt fuelled consumer boom. Or as it was more prosaically put: how much more could Americans continue to spend more than they earned? Would not the interest and other payments on these debts sooner or later reach unsustainable levels?

Now, it could be pointed out that although American debt accumulated by foreigners had reached 75% of US GDP, American investments abroad had grown to 50% of GDP. Net debt was therefore a far more comfortable 25% of GDP. Furthermore, US investments abroad tended to bring significantly larger returns than investments in the US. This was even more so given that much of the debt was now being accumulated by China along with other emerging market economies in the form of low interest US treasury bills, as a result of them seeking to maintain fixed exchange rates. This differential in the rate of returns between US investments abroad and foreign investments in the USA meant that the US economy taken as a whole could run up a substantial net debt before it reached the slippery slope of ‘Ponzi’ financing where it would in effect be borrowing more money in order to pay off the interest on existing loans. Even when it had reached this point of moving into ‘Ponzi financing’, it would still take a number of years before the burden of debt would become a serious problem.

By 2007 there were strong indications that the ‘financial imbalances’ were being unwound. Capital accumulation in the US had begun to pick up speed, taking up the strain of maintaining economic growth. Rising tax revenues from the expanding economy had reduced the government budget deficit, while rising exports was reducing the US trade deficit with the rest of the world.

Nevertheless there remained concerns amongst more conservative bourgeois commentators, who viewed China more in terms of a future threat rather than as a probationary member of the ‘international community’ that was offering lucrative profit opportunities. For them the issue was not so much the size of the mounting debts of either the US government or the US economy as a whole – and hence the problem of paying them back at some point in the future - but rather the issue was the danger posed by the fact that a large and growing proportion of these debts were held by the Chinese state. In 2000 China accounted for half the trade surplus of the ‘newly emerging market economies’ of east and south-east Asia with the rest of the world. By 2005, with most of east and south-east Asian exports being funnelled through China, it accounted for virtually all the region’s trade surplus. As a result, the Asian dollar surplus had become increasingly concentrated in China. In recycling this dollar surplus, the Chinese monetary authorities had become by far the largest purchaser of US government treasury bills. Thus the day to day financing of the US government had become dependent on the continuing goodwill of the Chinese state.

In the event of a political confrontation between the USA and China – say for example due to a flare up over the security of Taiwan – it was argued that the Chinese could exercise considerable leverage over the USA by threatening to stop buying its treasury bills. Alternatively the Chinese monetary authorities may, for purely economic reasons, decide that they had accumulated more than enough dollar holdings to insure themselves against some unforeseen economic crisis and they would be better off buying securities issued by Japanese and European governments that offered a superior rate of return.

For whatever reason, whether political or economic, a decision by the Chinese state to substantially reduce its dollar holdings would cause a sharp fall in the US dollar. The Federal Reserve Board would be obliged to raise interest rates to exorbitant levels, both in order to attract the money necessary to keep the US government functioning and to defend the value of dollar. A hike in rates would then bring the US economy shuddering to a halt.

But it could be countered that such scenarios were unlikely because it was not in the interest of China to cause an economic crisis in the US, since this would bring its own export-led growth to an abrupt halt. As a political weapon, a sudden reduction in China’s dollar holdings was something of a nuclear option that could ensure the mutually assured economic destruction of all parties. Furthermore, it could be pointed out that from about 2005 China had already begun to rebalance its foreign exchange reserves by reducing the proportion held in the form of dollar denominated assets.12 But this rebalancing had necessarily been very gradual for fear of sparking a financial panic. If the market became convinced that the Chinese monetary authorities were to substantially reduce their dollar holdings, rather than merely accumulate them at a slightly slower rate, then speculators would rush to sell US government assets and US dollars triggering an economic crisis. Indeed, for the time being, it could be argued that the Chinese state was for all intents and purposes locked into the continued financing of US debts.

The mainstream view of bourgeois commentators and economists therefore considered such scenarios as being unlikely. However, if the mutually reinforcing dynamic of growth between China and the US was to break down it was generally accepted that this would be due the ‘financial imbalances’ arising from this dynamic causing a crisis in the foreign exchange markets resulting from a collapse in the exchange rate of the US dollar. But as we now know the crisis broke out in the global banking system not in the foreign exchange markets, or the market for US treasury bills - both of which remained remarkably stable given the scale of the financial crisis. The reason for this is that too much focus was placed on the accumulation of debt rather than on the wider impact of the financial flows that was giving rise to this stock of debt.

As we have seen, the demand for loanable capital from the global banking and financial markets to finance the rise of China had been limited. Yet, as we have now seen, China has provided a plentiful supply of short term loanable capital in the form of its purchase of US treasury bills. Short term money-capital that would have previously been invested in US treasury bills have been displaced into other financial markets. The supply of Chinese funds into the US Treasury Bill market has thereby served to swell the pool of loanable money-capital across all the global financial markets.

Yet this is not all. As we have seen, China’s rapid growth has pushed up world demand for primary commodities. This has meant the producers of such commodities have made major gains in trade and, as a result many have built up substantial trade surpluses. This is particularly the case for the oil exporting economies of the Middle East. The growing world demand for oil, largely driven by China, coupled with the decline of the old oil fields of the North Sea and Alaska, has led to the price of oil tripling in price between 2001 and 2007. With the lack of internal investment opportunities, other than the construction of super-luxury island resorts, and with much of the oil revenues flowing to the state, these windfall gains have taken the form of ‘sovereign wealth funds’. These funds have been set up to make investments abroad so as to secure future income for the Middle Eastern states when their oil eventually runs out. To a large but by no means exclusive part, these sovereign wealth funds have been used to buy up US and other government bonds, corporate bonds and equities and other financial assets traded on the global markets, as well as being deposited in western banks.

Thus the rise of China has both directly and indirectly contributed to the oversupply of loanable money-capital in the global financial system that can be seen to be the cause of the growing fragility and overexpansion of global banking and finance capital. Indeed, as Ben Bernanke, the current Chairman of the US Federal Reserve Board, has now with hindsight concluded:

In my view…it is impossible to understand this crisis without reference to the global imbalances in trade and capital flows that began in the latter half of the 1990s.13

But it was perhaps not only the sheer volume of loanable money-capital supplied by both China and the sovereign wealth funds that was important in contributing to the fragility of the financial system but also their nature. China’s purchase of foreign assets on the global financial markets was determined by the policy objective of controlling the rate of exchange of the Yuan to the US dollar; while the sovereign wealth fund’s was to make long term investments. Neither China nor the Middle Eastern governments were interested in making short term speculative profits. As such their investment flows were immune from the day to day shifts in market sentiment. They thereby provided financial markets with an important ballast against speculative volatility that contributed to the ‘great moderation’ and the complacency that it bred.

However, although Ben Bernanke may blame the Chinese, the international financial imbalances caused by the rise of China are only part of the story. We must now turn our attention back to the financial imbalances at the heart of the global accumulation of capital - that is the USA.

The over expansion of finance and the US economy – old and new

The US corporate ‘savings glut’
The dot.com crash brought the surge in investment in the US that had accompanied the emergence of the ‘new economy’ to an abrupt halt. As in any recession, companies realised that the growth projections in sales and profits which had justified high levels of investment during the heady days of the boom now looked decidedly shaky. If they were to avoid bankruptcy or hostile take-over bids, they had to abandon investment plans aimed at expanding their operations and instead set about cutting costs. Given that a substantial part of the surge in investment which had fuelled the boom had been financed by bank loans or the issue of shares or bonds on the financial markets, many companies found themselves in a precarious financial position. The first call on any profits they made had to be the paying down of debt and maintaining high dividend payouts to sustain shareholder value.

As we have previously pointed out, the recession that followed the dot.com crash proved to be particularly mild. After a brief period of retrenchment profit rates were soon restored. However, while profits made a quick recovery, investment in the real accumulation of capital proved to be far more protracted. Rather than re-investing the increase in their profits in expanding their business, companies continued to use it to pay down their debt, or in other ways improve their financial position.

This gave rise to a rather peculiar situation. Except for brief periods during an economic recession, the corporate sector as a whole would expect to be a net borrower. However, since the dot.com crash the US non-financial corporate sector has become a substantial net saver (see FT diagram). Indeed, it was a result of such prolonged net saving that much of corporate America found itself in an exceptionally strong financial position that allowed it to weather the credit crunch and the subsequent near meltdown of the global banking system so well. However, although they played an important part in insulating the ‘real economy’ from the impact of the financial crisis, the accumulated financial surpluses of the non-financial corporate sector can be seen to have played a significant role in causing the financial crisis in the first place. To understand this we must take a closer and disaggregated look at the net savings of the US corporate sector.

As we have seen, the global banking and financial system had played a major role in the take off of the ‘new economy’ in the 1990s. Most of the myriad of start up dot.coms had been financed by generous bank loans and share issues. No one, least of all bankers and investors, could predict which band of the computer geeks that turned up at the banks’ doors with a seemingly plausible business plan would prove to be the next Mircosoft. Many would never even break even. However, it was enough for just one to prove commercially viable and the returns could be astronomical. However, following the dot.com crash the structure and direction of development of the ‘new economy’ had begun to settle down. Mircrosoft, Google and Apple had become well-established major corporations, and the dot.coms that had survived the cull following the crash could stake out most of the available niches in the ‘new economy’. There was clearly less room for new entrants, and thus less need for starting capital. Those dot.coms that had survived the cull, were now up and running and making real, as opposed to prospective, profits. With the high rates of profit now being earned in the ‘new economy’, companies could fund most of their investment out of their own profits and had little need for external financing. The capital accumulation in the ‘new economy’ had taken off and its expansion had become more or less self-sustaining.

Thus, although the rate of investment in the ‘new economy’, unlike other parts of the economy, recovered rapidly after the dot.com boom, its demand for loanable money capital from the banks and the financial markets declined. However, in the ‘old economy’ the relation to the global banking and financial system was the reverse of that of the ‘new economy’. Whereas the ‘new economy’ had been a source of demand, the ‘old economy’ had been a source of supply of loanable funds.

As we have seen, the release of finance had imposed on the management of even the largest publicly quoted corporation, the overriding imperative to ‘maximise shareholder value’. To do this it was necessary to regularly distribute a large amount of profit the company made in the form of dividends to its shareholders. This meant that mangers were under pressure to increase profits or squeeze the amount of profit retained for re-investment into expanding the business. Failure to ensure high and regular returns on its shares would soon lead to investors selling their shares in order to buy other company’s shares that offered better returns. This would then soon lead to a sharp drop in the company’s share price, and hence to a fall in its stock market valuation. With its shares so cheap, the company would then be ripe for a hostile takeover bid and the old management would then face being replaced by a new management team willing to either force through the changes necessary to restore shareholder value, or else to oversee the whole or partial liquidation of the company through the sale of its assets. To the extent that they were not simply spent on consumption but reinvested on the financial markets, or deposited with banks, the increased dividends served to swell the supply of loanable money-capital flowing into the global banking and financial system.

However, from the late 1990s the imperative to ‘maximise shareholder value’, under the peril of hostile takeover bids, was intensified. In a period when loanable capital had been in relatively short supply, and when interest rates had been high, the main threat of a hostile takeover bid was from rival companies of at least a similar size, and operating in the same or a closely related industry. With loanable funds limited, any large scale takeover bid would find it difficult to raise enough funds to buy up sufficient shares to give overall control simply in cash. Instead any potential predator would have to offer to pay for shares, all or in part, with their own shares. This meant that any predator had to a corporation with a stock market valuation sufficiently large to swallow its prey. Furthermore, high interest rates meant that any takeover had to offer the prospects of substantial gains to make it worthwhile. The prospective gains from a takeover had to at least cover the interest on the funds borrowed, and be sufficient to offset any downward pressure in market valuation of the predator company due to the issuing of new shares to make the offer. Only rival firms could usually hope to make sufficient gains from any takeover through any synergies that could be obtained between the operations of the two firms, through the economies of scale that could be gained from merging the operations of two firms or by simply eliminating a close competitor. Simply appointing a more ruthless management team was, by itself, unlikely to be sufficient.

In a period of increasing abundance of loanable funds and low interest rates the number of potential predators is greatly increased by the feasibility of ‘leveraged buy outs’. Any consortium of well connected and wealthy businessmen could now launch a successful takeover of a large corporation through a ‘leveraged buy-out’. With an abundance of loanable funds, such a consortium need only advance a tenth, a twentieth or even as little as a thirtieth of the sum required to make a successful takeover bid of their own money, since they can easily borrow the rest. Furthermore, with interest rates so low, the new management team they hire to run the business need only make a marginal gain in the company’s stock market valuation before the consortium can sell the firm on, and with the proceeds pay off the loans they borrowed with interest and make a handsome return on the capital they themselves advanced.

In the rapidly expanding industries of the ‘new economy’ the best defence against hostile takeovers has been to reinvest rising profits in expanding the business to ensure the continued growth of profits in the near future. The prospect that investment in expanding the business now will soon lead to higher profits and thus higher dividend payments in the future should be sufficient to keep the stock market valuations high. However, in the ‘old economy’, which by any reasonable definition still comprises the bulk of the US economy, such a strategy is far less viable. Particularly for the old Fordist industries that have long since reached maturity, any investment in the real accumulation of capital is unlikely to bring quick returns. As such, any prospective profits from such investment are likely to be beyond the time horizon of most participants in the financial markets. They are therefore unlikely to carry much weight, however large they may be, on the stock market valuations.

As a result the primary response of companies and corporations in the ‘old economy’ to the threat of hostile takeovers has been to use the proceeds of rising profits to buy off the threat of hostile takeovers. Firstly, increased profits have been distributed in the form of higher dividend payments. Secondly increased profits have been used to pay down debt. Thirdly, in what has been a relatively novel defensive strategy that has been developed over the past decade, increased profits have been used to buy back the company’s own shares. As a result, a large part of the rising profits in the ‘old economy’ have flowed into the global banking and financial system in the form of free loanable money capital.

But like danegeld,14 buying off hostile attacks only serves to encourage the attackers to come back for more. By paying higher dividends, by paying down debt or by buying back shares, in order to ward off the danger that they themselves might face a hostile takeover, individual companies only serve to swell the supply of loanable money-capital that in general makes such attacks more likely. There has therefore been a degree of self perpetuation in the process that has seen both a growing supply of loanable money capital flowing into the banking and financial system and the slow recovery of investment into the real accumulation of capital in the US.

As we have seen, international financial imbalances, the take off of the ‘new economy’ and the continued liquidation of capital within the ‘old economy’ in the USA and other advanced capitalist economies, has resulted in an over-supply of free loanable money-capital. But before we can see how this oversupply of investable funds produced the recent financial crisis we must consider its impact in bringing about an over-accumulation of banking and finance, particularly in the USA.

The over accumulation of finance and banking
What has struck most observers of the emergence of the global finance and banking system over the past three decades has been the sheer speed of its expansion. This rapid growth has meant the growing relative importance of the financial sector. In the USA, where of course the heart of global finance and banking is located, the financial sector now accounts for around 20% of GDP. But, perhaps far more significantly, the financial sector accounts for around 40% of the profits made by US corporations. This means that the financial sector has been able to capture more than its fair share of profits, and this has been reflected in the above average rates of profits made by most banks and other financial institutions. How has the financial sector been able to sustain such rapid expansion and high levels of profitability?

Banking and finance as such does not produce surplus value directly. Financial profits arise from the appropriation of surplus value produced and realised in the production and circulation of commodities in the ‘real economy’. To this extent finance could be said to be parasitical on the real accumulation of capital. However, although the financial sector does not directly produce surplus value, it does play an important role in facilitating the process of capital accumulation. Thus, for example, the financial system is able to bring about substantial reductions in the costs of making monetary transaction. The provision of bank credit and overdraft facilities greatly reduces the need for capital to be held idle in the form of money reserves. And perhaps most importantly, the financial system serves to convert the small short term savings of the population into loanable money capital that can be used to support long term investment. By providing such savings and services to ‘real capitals’ banks and financial companies are able to extract a share of the surplus value they have produced in the form of commissions, fees and interest. However, while this may explain the basis on which banks and other financial companies derive their profits, it does not explain how the financial sector has been able to sustain such an exceptionally high profitability over the past few decades.

Now it is true as many critics of high finance maintain that the profitability of the financial sector has been boosted by its rather privileged position. Repeatedly over the past three decades the banks and other financial companies have been bailed out by governments after the bursting of speculative bubbles. From the ‘third world’ debt crisis of the early 1980s to the recent near meltdown of the global financial system following the collapse of Lehman Brothers, governments and monetary authorities have time after time been obliged to in effect ‘nationalise’ the losses of the financial system. What is more, the political power of the financial sector has led to the steady reduction in banking regulations that serve to limit the over expansion of finance and excessive risk taking that lead to speculative bubbles. As a result financial companies have been able to make more risky investments that promise big profits knowing that if things turn bad a large slice of the losses will be mopped up by the authorities. Furthermore, the financial sector can be seen to be under-taxed. Thus, for example, while companies involved the production and sale of commodities are usually subject to some form of sales tax such as VAT, financial transactions and services are usually exempt. More importantly the very mobility of finance allows the financial sector to avoid or evade tax, or make profits from helping corporations and individuals to do likewise.

It is no doubt true that bailouts and low taxes have contributed greatly to both the rapid expansion and the high profitability of the financial sector. However, we would argue the basis for such a sustained expansion and high profitability over the last thirty or so years has been the role the global financial system has played in bringing about the restructuring of global capital accumulation and the consequent restoration of profit rates. As we have seen, the development of global banking and finance has played an important role in the translocation of capital from industries and regions where profits are low and capital is over accumulated to new industries and regions where there is at least the prospect of high rates of profit. By mobilising loanable money capital to support the opening up of new areas of capital accumulation, by handling the vast increase in international money transactions this has entailed and by spreading and managing the risks of such speculative investments, the global banking and financial system has been able to take a significant cut in the increased profits that have resulted.

However we explain the rapid expansion and high profitability of the financial sector one further question remains: why has the rate of profit in the financial sector remained so high? Why hasn’t capital rushed into the financial sector to take advantage of the high profits that can be made there and thereby bring about a reduction in its rate of profit? There are formidable barriers to entry into large areas of the financial sector, particularly banking. To prevent any mountebank running away with other peoples’ money, there are strict legal requirements and restrictions on setting up banks and other similar institutions. The success of banks and other major financial companies depends on having specialist financial expertise, business connections and a long established reputation that cannot easily be reproduced by new entrants into the sector. As a result of such barriers most capital accumulation in the financial sector has been carried out by long-established banks and financial companies that have been able to sustain higher than average rates of profit.

Nevertheless there has been a rapid growth in small companies, such as hedge funds, that have been able to carve out distinct niches for themselves in the less regulated and more exotic parts of the financial system. But perhaps more importantly there has been, particularly over the past decade, a growing encroachment into the financial sector by large industrial and commercial corporations.

With the pressure exerted by financial markets to maximise shareholder value there has come what we term the ‘financialisation’ of industrial and commercial corporations. Such corporations are not so much in the business of producing or selling specific commodities but in making money. Under pressure to make quick returns the prospect of moving into aspects of finance has been attractive to many corporations that have large financial flows. Thus, for example, over the last ten years or so, many corporations have moved away from relying on overdrafts on their bank accounts to cover fluctuations in their cash flows. Instead they have issued ‘commercial paper’ – that is short term IOUs – that can be bought and sold on the financial markets. Although they may have to employ the services of an investment bank to manage the issue and redemption of such ‘commercial paper’, they save by being able to borrow at far lower interest rates than they would on an overdraft. They thereby take a cut of profits that would otherwise be made by their bank. However, some corporations have gone far further and opened up their own financial operations. General Motors for example moved from providing car loans to setting up its own mortgage company – GMAC – which ended up being bailed out after the bursting of the sub-prime mortgage bubble.15

Thus there has been a slow but significant encroachment of commercial and industrial corporations into the financial sector. By taking a slice of financial profits this encroachment has contributed to the downward pressure on profit margins in finance and banking. But this move into finance has not been due to a fall in the general rate of profit ruling in the industrial and commercial sectors of the economy, as orthodox Marxists might insist, which if anything have risen. On the contrary it has been due to the exceptionally high rates of profit that have arisen in the financial sector. Indeed, as we shall see, we might well conclude that it was not a low or falling rate of profit, but high though uneven rates of profits that have been the ‘ultimate cause’ of the crisis.

The over-supply of loanable money-capital and the causes of the recent crisis concluded
As we have argued, the emergence of global finance and banking has played a vital role in what Schumpeter would call the process of ‘creative destruction’ that resulted in the long economic upswing. In what may be described as the first phase of neoliberalism – that is from the late 1970s to the late 1980s – it had been the destructive side of this process that had been to the fore. The rise of global banking and finance played an important role in facilitating the neoliberal counter-offensive against the working class - providing the ‘economic imperatives’ necessary to roll back the gains of the post-war settlements. At the same time it liquidated capital fixed in the old Fordist industries in the advanced capitalist economies.

In what we may term the second phase – from the late 1980s to the late 1990s – the ‘creative’ side of this process from the point of view of capital became more prominent. Global banking and finance played an important role in facilitating the transfer of capital necessary for the take off of the ‘new economy’ and the ‘newly emerging market economies’ of Asia and elsewhere, which were to provide the basis for the long upswing.

However, in what we consider as the third phase – from the late 1990s up until the credit crunch of 2007 - the further development in the upswing was to have important implications for the character of global banking and finance. As we have seen, the rise of China, the take off of sustained capital accumulation of capital in the ‘new economy’ together with the continued liquidation of capital in the less profitable parts of the ‘old economy’ resulted in a situation where there was an increasing oversupply of loanable money capital.

The increasing abundance of loanable money-capital flowing through the global banking and financial system can be seen to have had two distinct consequences. Firstly, it produced a decline in financial volatility compared with the turbulence of the previous decade, since there was now plenty of loanable money-capital to go round the various spheres and areas of investment. This provided the basis of what was to be known as the ‘great moderation’ in financial markets following the dot.com crash.

Secondly, the abundance of loanable money-capital placed downward pressure on interest rates. This, together with increased competition due to overaccumulation of capital in the financial sector, depressed the profit margins of banks and other financial institutions.

In order to offset declining profit margins on their rate of profits, banks and other financial institutions sought to maximise the volume of their loans and other financial transactions. Encouraged by the complacency engendered by the ‘great moderation’, there was as a result a pressure to take on more risky loans and investments, as well as to reduce financial reserves to an absolute minimum. As a consequence, the global banking and financial system became increasingly overextended and fragile.

At first much of this oversupply of loanable money capital had been mitigated by the sharp increase in US government borrowing that had served to alleviate the impact of the dot.com crash. This had seen the US budget move from a surplus of 2% to a deficit of 4% of GDP in the first four years of Bush (jnr’s) term of office. However, after the re-election of Bush the US government budget deficit had stabilised and had begun to fall. Thus in the three years before the credit crunch there had been a rapid growth in the relative oversupply of loanable capital in the global banking and financial system. This was then further exacerbated by the attempt by the monetary authorities to raise interest rates which only served to invert the ‘yield curve’ and squeeze financial profit margins.

As a consequence, there was a frantic effort on the part of banks to expand loans and other financial transactions and ‘a search for yield’. The tendency towards the increasing fragility of the global banking and financial system was thereby greatly accelerated creating the conditions for the financial crisis of 2007-8 that we considered in detail in Part I of this article.

Conclusion

The financial crisis came to the rescue of ‘stagnationist’ radical and Marxist theorists, who up until then had been finding it increasingly difficult to explain away the continuation of the long economic upswing of the past two decades. Certainly it could be admitted that the almighty financial crash at the very heart of the system had finally happened. For the ‘upswingers’ the option seemed either to concur with most bourgeois commentators and conclude that the financial crisis was merely the result of some horrendous accident due to misguided monetary and regulatory policy, or rejoin the ‘stagnationist’ camp by claiming that the crisis marked the beginning of a long economic downswing.

Yet, as we have argued, there seems little to suggest we have entered a long downswing, or that capitalism is now mired in stagnation other than the financial crisis itself. Indeed the rapid recovery in profits, and the confidence of much of the bourgeoisie in the long term prospects of renewed capital accumulation, would seem to suggest otherwise.16 But if global capitalism is still in the middle of a long upswing, with historically high rates of profits, how are we to explain the unforeseen financial crisis of 2007-08?

As we have long argued, against the ‘stagnationist’ orthodoxy, ‘upswing’ theory has been correct in grasping that the restructuring of the global accumulation of capital that has occurred in the past decade, particularly the integration into the world economy of China and Asia, has led to the restoration of profit rates and, as a consequence, a sustained economic upswing. But as we now recognise, the problem is that the upswing theory has failed to adequately grasp the importance of the emergence of global banking and finance, and the role this has played in bringing about this restructuring.

Thus, in order to overcome the limitations of both the ‘stagnationist’ and ‘upswinger’ theories of the crisis it was necessary to examine the relation between the emergence and development of global banking and finance and the global restructuring of real capital accumulation that has occurred over the past thirty years. On the basis of this examination we have been able to conclude that the financial crisis of 2007-8 was caused neither by an accident due to misguided policy, nor a crisis in the financial system that simply reflected an underlying crisis of stagnation of the real accumulation of capital. But instead, the underlying cause of the financial crisis was an oversupply of loanable money-capital within the global banking and financial system that has arisen since the late 1990s. This in turn has been the result of developments in the real accumulation of capital - such as the rise of China, the take off of the ‘new economy’ and the continued liquidation of the ‘old economy’ - that have been central to sustaining the long upturn.

Hence, we might tentatively conclude that the nature and significance of the financial crisis is not that of a decisive turning point leading to an economic downturn or the end of neoliberalism as many have supposed, but more of a point of inflection pointing to a new phase in the long upturn.17 The significance of this new phase and the implications it has for the future development of global capitalism and the struggle against it is a question that we have no space to take up here.

  • 1Originally we intended to begin Part II of this article with a critical review of the more salient Marxist and radical Keynesian theories of the current crisis. However, lack of space and time has meant that we decided to omit what could have easily become a rather lengthy academic exercise.
  • 2Of course, the notion that capitalism is in decline has been a central tenet of traditional Marxism for the past hundred years (see ‘Theory of decline or the decline of theory’ in Aufheben #2, 3 and 4. But also see our self-critique of this article at http://libcom.org/aufheben/decadence ). As a result of the Great Depression, in the 1930s and 1940s such a notion was also shared by many bourgeois economic thinkers. Schumpeter, for example, in his Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy lamented the passing of the entrepreneurial spirit of nineteenth century capitalism and saw the evolution of capitalism towards a bureaucratic state socialism as almost inevitable. Keynes accepted Schumpeter’s prognosis, but, following John Stuart Mill, took a more sanguine view. Keynes looked forward to the time when capitalism would slow down and eventually reach a steady state in which vulgar money grabbing would no longer be necessary. His only concern was that capitalism would run out of steam before material scarcity could be abolished and wage-labour could be reduced to a minimum.
  • 3Permanent Revolution are perhaps the most consistent vociferous proponents of the ‘upswing’ thesis. Also see our article on China in Aufheben #14.
  • 4This failure to develop an adequate theory of the development of global banking and finance can also be traced back to the inadequacies of both Marx’s and Keynes’s theories of finance. Marx’s theory of money and finance is largely contained in Part V of Volume III of Capital. But this was cobbled together by Engels from various notebooks left by Marx after his death and remains very far from constituting a finished worked-out theory. It is true that Hilferding in his celebrated book Finance Capital attempted to develop and update Marx’s theory of money and finance. However, Hilferding’s theory is based on the particular concrete circumstance of Germany at the beginning of the twentieth century and hence its applicability to the analysis of modern global banking and finance is limited. More recently there has been some important work in attempting to develop systematically a Marxian theory of money and finance. See for example, The Political Economy of Money and Finance by Makoto Itoh and Costas Lapavitsas. However, this remains at too high a level of abstraction to be of much use in analysing the concrete circumstance of the recent financial crisis. Keynes was first and foremost a ‘monetary economist’. However, his primary aim, particularly in his seminal work The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, had been to persuade politicians and policymakers, who had been educated in neoclassical economic theory, to save capitalism through state intervention. To do this Keynes presented his theory as merely a generalisation of neoclassical monetary theory, which saw banks and financial markets as passive intermediaries between individual savers and individual entrepreneurs. Thus, although he made a number of observations and asides that go beyond the abstract conceptions of neoclassical monetary economics that have been taken up by his more radical disciples, the core of Keynes’s theory remains confined within bourgeois economic orthodoxy. As a result it has been relatively easy for mainstream bourgeois economic theory to re-assimilate Keynes’s theory as a special case that applies to the exceptional circumstances when the economy becomes stuck in a ‘sub-optimal equilibrium’.
  • 5The crisis has certainly brought to the fore the writings of the rather idiosyncratic and neglected Keynesian economists H. Minsky. In short, Minsky argued that during a period of financial stability what he termed the financial structure of a capitalist economy would tend to become increasingly fragile. Continued financial stability encouraged the growth in confidence that loans would paid back. Reserves against bad loans would be reduced, financial innovations would be devised to get round existing regulations that aimed to ensure financial prudence and regulators would become complacent. Short term loans would be rolled over to finance long term investments and the as a result the financial structure would become increasingly speculative. As a result, eventually even a minor shock to the financial structure of the economy could cause a serious financial crisis. The crisis would then lead to renewed efforts at financial regulator and a return to financial prudence. This Minskyian financial cycle, in which financial stability produces financial instability, has been seized on by both mainstream and radical theorists to explain the recent financial crisis. Certainly at first sight it would appear to provide a neat explanation of how the sub-prime mortgage crisis served as a ‘Minsky moment’ that ended the ‘great moderation’. But on closer inspection the Minskyian explanation is not so neat after all. Firstly, Minsky’s notion of the ‘financial structure’ does not merely include banks and financial institutions but all economic actors such as businesses and individual households. Indeed this had been central for Minsky in order to show how a financial crisis such as the Wall Street crash could have such an impact on the real economy to create the Great Depression of the 1930s. But, as we shall, the great moderation which had preceded the credit crunch had seen non-financial corporate sector become more financially sound not less. Secondly, to the extent that it is taken to explain the recent financial crisis, the less it is able to explain the financial turbulence of the 1980s and 1990s when financial crises were far more frequent.
  • 6From this perspective the crisis might be viewed like a tyre blow out in a Formula One race. But for the adept steering of the driver the crash could have been far more serious. Nevertheless the car as whole remains a functioning high performance vehicle. All that needs to be done is to fit a more suitable tyre and to remind the driver not to accelerate so fast out of a tight corner and all will be ok except for the minutes lost during the pit stop.
  • 7See for example Fixing Global Finance by Martin Wolf and ‘Global Imbalances and the Financial Crisis’, Paper presented to the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Asia Economic Policy Conference, October 2009, by M. Obstfeld and K. Rogoff.
  • 8For an attempt to quantify the impact of international imbalances on US interest rates see ‘International capital Flows and U.S. Interest Rates’ F.E.Warnock & V.C. Warnock in Journal of International Money and Finance, 28 (6).
  • 9The ‘yield curve’ relates the interest rates on government securities of increasing maturities. Given that the risk of governments major economies like the US, the US or Germany is considered negligible, the ‘yield curve’ indicates the relation between long and short term loans independent of variations in risk. Usually the yield curve is upward sloping: that is the longer the loan the higher the interest.
  • 10Capital I p.236 Penguin edition. But as Engels notes on the same page ‘The monetary crisis, defined in the text as a particular phase of every general industrial and commercial crisis, must be clearly distinguished from the special sort of crisis, also called a monetary crisis, which may appear independently of the rest, and only affects industry and commerce by its backwash. The pivot of these crises is to be found in money capital, and their immediate sphere of impact is therefore banking, the stock exchange and finance’. Thus as Itoh and Lapavitsas have pointed out, there are two quite distinct types of financial crises. The first arising from the contradictions of real capital accumulation, the second arising from with the financial system itself. The financial crisis of 2007-8 would seem closer to the second type.
  • 11‘An Essay on the Revived Bretton Woods System’, NBER Working Paper Series, 2003, by M.P.Dooley, D. Folkerts-Landau and Peter Garber.
  • 12Chinese monetary authorities were able to begin a gradual rebalancing of its foreign currency reserves for two reasons. Firstly, the opening up of other markets, particularly those in Europe, to Chinese exports meant that a larger proportion of export earnings in to China took the form of currencies other than the US dollar. Secondly, China allowed the a gradual but controlled appreciation of the Yuan against the US dollar.
  • 13‘Financial Reform to Address Systemic Risk’. Speech given by Ben Bernanke at the Council on Foreign Relations, Washington, D.C. March 2009.
    http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20090310a.htm
  • 14Danegeld (‘Dane's gold’ or Danish Tax) was a tax raised to pay tribute to Viking raiders to save a kingdom from being ravaged from 991 AD. However, once paid, it marked out those willing to pay as ‘easy marks’ – and the raiders would keep coming back demanding more.
  • 15It can be argued that it was in part the decline in corporate deposits that obliged banks to increasingly fund mortgage lending by selling mortgage backed securities on the financial markets.
  • 16Of course, the rapid recovery in profits following the crisis has yet to result in a surge in investment and thus real capital accumulation. Even if capital accumulation does take off the austerity measures imposed by governments across Europe is likely to mean economic recovery will be slow for several years.
  • 17The crisis could be seen as an earthquake caused by the shifting tectonic plates of global capital accumulation as the centre of accumulation gradually shifts away from the USA and the old advanced capitalist economies towards China and Asia.

Comments

S. Artesian

13 years 1 month ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on October 30, 2011

Hence, we might tentatively conclude that the nature and significance of the financial crisis is not that of a decisive turning point leading to an economic downturn or the end of neoliberalism as many have supposed, but more of a point of inflection pointing to a new phase in the long upturn.17 The significance of this new phase and the implications it has for the future development of global capitalism and the struggle against it is a question that we have no space to take up here.

Right-- a point of inflection for a new upturn?

Well, look boys and girls. It's been 4 years, going on 5. Recovery being the weakest on record, where such recovery can even be measured. A new phase in the long upturn? These people need to look at how short-lived, skimpy, meager the upturn was out of the 2003 recession.

I think Aufheben will be eating those words soon enough-- inflection point pointing to a new phase in the long upturn. Only if we recognize that in capitalism, advanced decrepit capitalism, there is no longer a meaningful distinction between upturn and contraction.

baboon

13 years 1 month ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by baboon on October 31, 2011

I'd say it's been 7 decades going on 8 and, of course, one can't leave the Second World War out of this equasion. And particularly since the late 1960s, each recession has been getting steadily worse, based on the extension of credit and debt as they have been and continue to be.

"A point of inflection pointing to a new phase in a long upturn" is just a fancy way of defending the perpetuity of capitalism.

MarxTrek

13 years 1 month ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by MarxTrek on November 2, 2011

I am not so sure that Aufheben will be eating those words. What I took away from part 1 & 2 and in addition to having almost finished the Marazzi piece The Violence of Financial Capitalism is that this crisis is a process of capital accumulation and that the long upturn in Aufheben's crisis analysis reflects this point. More to come after shower and work.

S. Artesian

13 years 1 month ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on November 2, 2011

That's like saying WW1, the 1920s Great Depression, WW2, post-WW2 were all processes of capital accumulation, and therefore there is reason to distinguish one from the other and that the Great Depression was an "inflection point" for a long upturn.

Well, of course these eras are all expressions of the movement, the antagonisms of capitalist accumulation. We are living in the world of capitalism, aren't we?

The distinction however, between WW2 and post-WW2 is that accumulation of capital, of value, post WW2 required the previous destruction of use value, including the use value of labor power in the Great Depression and WW2.

Not everything's an upturn. Look at the real upturn in the US 1993-2000 and tell me how 2007-2011 bears any resemblance to that, or even to the 1990-1992 period?

Aufheben IMO is basing its analysis on its ideology-- an ideological commitment to the notion that capitalist crisis is a countervailing tendency to the decline in profitability. Certain that's what a "crisis" is.

This, like the Great Depression, is more than a "crisis." Much more. This is the structural inability of capital to restore the basis for expanded accumulation via a crisis.

S. Artesian

13 years 1 month ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on November 2, 2011

It's an attempt to restore profitability, to aggrandize a greater proportion of surplus value; the problem then becomes in capitalizing that greater aggrandizement, the expansion, as the greater aggrandizement itself sooner or later has to be directed towards the expansion of the means of production, which then drives down the profitability.

At a certain point, the rate of accumulation cannot be sustained, and cannot sustain in turn the needed profitability.

In the run-up to the current conditions, the US fashioned its post 2003 recovery around 2 major axes: 1) driving down the cost of labor below its 2000 peak 2) draconian controls on capital spending programs. The "replacement ratio" [capital spending as compared to capital consumption] in US industry actually declined to less than 1 until....2006 when spending had to increase as equipment was simply wearing out.

Guess what? That spending marked the peak in the rate of return on investment, and on fixed assets for US industry and manufacturing.

The above is obviously just a sketch of the forces at work.

Marx phrases it acutely, accurately, brilliant in vol 3. when he talks about overproduction as always overproduction of the means of production as capital--beyond the ability of capital to exploit labor power at a sufficient intensity.

MarxTrek

13 years 1 month ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by MarxTrek on November 2, 2011

I am not an economist just know of things in generalities and historically more so than through pure economic indicators or classic Marx (vol. 1-3). Aufheben and Marazzi seem to be able to apply the "real economy" or bread and butter issues and effects to the bigger financial economy where all the profit and surplus value seems to end up.

It would seem that we are entering into an economic situation where war is no longer used to destroy the burden of overproduction and but war being part policing a constant war, I know its getting cliche to say this but its seems to be reality more so than just whacky theory from European marxist academic rock stars.

WWI and WWII are different wars from: Korea, Vietnam, Iraq I and Afghanistan and Iraq II, and all the other military operations carried out in Africa, Asia, and South America. These post-WWII wars aren't wars destroying overproduction but rather wars to open up new markets or maintain markets. I don't see the wars fought after WWII happening to destroy overproduction. The wars today seem to be more about guarding and maintaining flows of capital. Also, the war came before the crisis.

"This, like the Great Depression, is more than a "crisis." Much more. This is the structural inability of capital to restore the basis for expanded accumulation via a crisis"

Or, as what I have gathered from Aufheben and the Marazzi piece, this crisis is not a crisis in capitalist accumulation but a process in accumulating capital. It would seem that capitalism is crisis capitalism and not that this crisis is not Capital's inability to accumulate.

Maybe we should see if we are agreeing on the differences in our arguments before going ahead and discussing this any deeper.

1. The crisis is away of accumulating capital/profit/surplus-value
2. The crisis is a crisis for capitalism in its inability to accumulate capital/profit/surplus-value.

or are we both missing each others point?

S. Artesian

13 years 1 month ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on November 2, 2011

MarxTrek

I am not an economist just know of things in generalities and historically more so than through pure economic indicators or classic Marx (vol. 1-3). Aufheben and Marazzi seem to be able to apply the "real economy" or bread and butter issues and effects to the bigger financial economy where all the profit and surplus value seems to end up.

It would seem that we are entering into an economic situation where war is no longer used to destroy the burden of overproduction and but war being part policing a constant war, I know its getting cliche to say this but its seems to be reality more so than just whacky theory from European marxist academic rock stars.

WWI and WWII are different wars from: Korea, Vietnam, Iraq I and Afghanistan and Iraq II, and all the other military operations carried out in Africa, Asia, and South America. These post-WWII wars aren't wars destroying overproduction but rather wars to open up new markets or maintain markets. I don't see the wars fought after WWII happening to destroy overproduction. The wars today seem to be more about guarding and maintaining flows of capital. Also, the war came before the crisis.

"This, like the Great Depression, is more than a "crisis." Much more. This is the structural inability of capital to restore the basis for expanded accumulation via a crisis"

Or, as what I have gathered from Aufheben and the Marazzi piece, this crisis is not a crisis in capitalist accumulation but a process in accumulating capital. It would seem that capitalism is crisis capitalism and not that this crisis is not Capital's inability to accumulate.

Maybe we should see if we are agreeing on the differences in our arguments before going ahead and discussing this any deeper.

1. The crisis is away of accumulating capital/profit/surplus-value
2. The crisis is a crisis for capitalism in its inability to accumulate capital/profit/surplus-value.

or are we both missing each others point?

Comrade,

Let me ask you just one question: You don't think the war against Iraq was a war in response to overproduction?

If you do not, then I think you need to go back and look at who was being blamed and by whom in 1998 when the price of oil broke below $10/barrel.

You need to look at the whole run-up to the war, with the low rate of return in the petroleum industry, the accumulation of new reserves, the decline in true lifting costs......and the ramping up of production by Iraq in order to exchange the oil for food and material.

And then you need to look at the recession in 2001, the "re-decline" of oil prices in 2002 after OPEC had intervened to raise them in 1999, and the saber rattling this precipitated by good old boys Bush and Cheney.

The war in Iraq had nothing to do with "opening up markets." It had everything to do with driving the price of oil up, and driving Iraq's production off the market, and looting part of the public treasury through all the private contracts, the public treasuries of both the US and Iraq.

I have no idea what the difference is between a crisis in accumulating capital and a crisis in capital accumulation, but like I said the current situation is much more than a crisis. And no way it's an inflection point marking a "new upturn."

Steven.

13 years 1 month ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Steven. on November 3, 2011

One thing I would like to know is if the statistics Aufheben used here about corporate profitability in the "real economy", i.e. that profits are still very high, are still correct, or if the situation has changed. I would have thought that as unemployment has shot up corporate profits would have taken a significant hit (I'm aware that they have in a few major retailers: M&S etc)

S. Artesian

13 years 1 month ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on November 3, 2011

Profits of non-financial industries in the US in 2010 certainly recovered from 2009 levels, but were still 25% below the 2007 mark.

Don't have similar stats on the EU.

Cutting employment in contractions has historically provided a boost to profits--- labor costs, and capital spending usually, are reduced providing better margins on reduced production.

MarxTrek

13 years 1 month ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by MarxTrek on November 3, 2011

so I slept on my comment and libcom timed out and I lost me comment. I will write more after work, again.

In short, oil production in Iraq is up and with Hussein gone the petro-dollar is safe from Iraq's 2000 shift over to the Euro in trading oil. Iraq is an open market for all to exploit and the looting of public funds has resulted in accumulation at higher rates than before and workers here in the US are eating the higher costs of living. The crisis is making accumulation grow not slow down.

S. Artesian

13 years 1 month ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on November 3, 2011

Yes, in short oil production in Iraq is now up, but still below 1996-1998 levels. The invasion of Iraq had nothing to do with Iraq's threat to shift to the euro [think about that comrade-- what would that do? It would make the euro stronger, which is exactly what the US wanted to happen post-2002. It would negatively impact EU exports-- which it has, except for Germany, which beat the snot out of its working class in the 90s and earlier part of the 2000-2010 decade].

Accumulation at higher rates than before? Not after 2006, and even in the period of recovery 2003-2007, I think the return of NET PPE was below that of the 1993-2000 period.

If the crisis is making accumulation grow, then we have to explain why profits are still 25% [in the US for non-financial corporations] below the 2007 level?

Or do you think somewhere outside the EU, the US, Japan-- do you think profit growth in Brazil, China, etc. makes up for the decline in the big 3?

I don't think so.

MarxTrek

13 years 1 month ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by MarxTrek on November 4, 2011

Is oil and non-financial corporations only up for discussion in talking about a decline in profit accumulation overproduction vs. Aufheben's upturn or a new process in accumulation?

It seems that the financial sector and real estate played a bigger role in Aufheben's article than Iraq and Oil did, maybe oil is being overproduced and profit is down, I am not certain, but again that is one industry. Does the overproduction of chips or soft drinks and decline in profit have just as much sway in criticizing Aufbehen's crisis article?

What I find interesting with Marazzi and Aufheben's articles is the total look at the economy and the hyper concentration of wealth/profit/accumulation of all sectors into the financial system. Some how buying a donut circulates back into this all encompassing financial sector at the very top. Extraction of wealth has become more perfected and we further alienated.

Again, I am no economists, but it seems that the financial sector has accumulated an ungodly amount of wealth/profit/liquid assets through this crisis and every other sector is going along, besides real estate,and here in the US prices are up and people, the same amount maybe a little bit more, are still pumping gas into their cars at a higher expense then in the early 2000s. I find it hard to see how an oil corporation isn't making more money off higher prices and a steady consumption of oil coupled with the opening up of Iraq's oil fields to the big western oil companies, an lets not forget the growing economy's needing more oil. Sure Saudi Arabia/OPEC is going to cut oil production but that is the same shit they did before, nothing really new there. Iraq was fought to open a comparable oil reserve to Saudi Arabia, keep oil under the petro-dollar, and some halfhearted attempts by Bush and company to reassert American "imperialist" interests.

What is new in this crisis is the massive looting, as said before, of public money and poured into the financial sector that is not being used to fix the crisis and restore the economy to pre-crisis days but rather just as accumulation for the entire financial sector to decide on what it wants to do with its newly acquired usable wealth/profit/etc.

The separation between capital accumulating more and us the workers and consumers to generate more wealth is being heightened through financialization.

Maybe I am out of bounds here...?

S. Artesian

13 years 1 month ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on November 4, 2011

Not out of bounds.. lots to be considered. But let's be clear: How does what you are describing amount to an inflection point in a "new upturn"?

MarxTrek

13 years 1 month ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by MarxTrek on November 5, 2011

I think the "upswing" or "new upturn" within financial-capitalism is explained within the Conclusion of Aufheben's, "Return of the Crisis (Part II)" though in coupling Aufheben's article with Christian Marazzi's, The Violence of Financial Capitalism it would seem that Aufheben has put too much focus on the possible outcome of Chinese domination, if my memory serves me correct. Marazzi allows for other possibilities and doesn’t seem to interested in predication. So maybe we actually do agree on Aufheben eating those words but not for the same reasons.
Having just finished Marazzi's text, I found the conclusion in that highly informative and will try to quote and paraphrase it for this discussion. I would just like to take this opportunity to suggest reading Marazzi’s text in its entirety because it dissects the crisis without resorting in suggesting a return Keynesianism.
“In order to save the banking-financial system from collapse with injections of liquidity, public intervention, be it national or supernational, reveals two things: on the one hand, the necessity to plug up with added demand (to prevent a crisis of over production) the surplus value produced in the expansive phase of the cycle through debt, on the access of goods produced in the ascending phase through layoffs and the worsening of living conditions. It is during this phase that we see a selloff of excess produced goods coupled with industrial and bank capital concentrations. Overcoming the subprime crisis caused the shift of debt from private to public sectors, but the public debt, increasing vertiginously more than anything else, is the result of the socialization of financial capital made with the taxpayers money and the creation of liquidity by monetary authorities. A kind of communism of capital where the state, i.e. the collectivity, caters to the needs of the “financial soviets,” i.e. banks, insurance companies, investment funds, and hedge funds, imposing a market dictatorship over society” (p.109-110).
"In our opinion, the divergence in accumulation rates between developed countries, Asian counties, and new developing countries should be analyzed on the basis of the global form of contemporary capitalism, keeping in mind the strategic roles of transnational companies that directly benefit from the high growth rates of developing countries, repatriating the surplus value realized there to invest it in financial markets, as well as keeping in mind the appearance of new political tools for coordination, intervention, and supernational control, like the G20, the IMF, the World Bank, the WTO, and the central banks of the main regional poles of development. The globalization of capital has internalized peripheral economies, forming the Empire theorized by Negri and Hardt--an empire in which the same logic of exploitation rules, even if articulated in different forms, and where the appropriation of wealth by a transnational capitalist oligarchy dominates. Today, the relationships are inside accumulation processes, every "outside" is already "inside" the process of capitalist growth..."(p.110-111).
"...This is made possible thanks to souring labor conditions, direct and indirect wage compression, precarizing labor and externalization processes of whole segments of production. That is, if the cost of labor is minimized and employment is reduced, profits increase and a part of them are invested in financial markets to guarantee financial rents. The mobility of capital, its orientation towards developing counties with high rates of profit and company delocalization are all processes that have contributed to increasing profits, without, however, triggering a new wave of general prosperity, rather an extreme polarization of incomes. We are witnessing a spiral growth sustained by global rates of accumulation"(p.113).
The new phase of accumulation is through financialization of every aspect of the economy. Debt, credit, rent, precarity, and what have you is becoming the key to production of accumulation/surplus-value/profit. Maybe this isn’t Aufheben’s “upswing” or “new upturn” as described in “Return of the Crisis” but with Marazzi’s text explains how this crisis created and is creating new accumulation possibilities, and the rising of profits for the financial sector, the financial sector is just, at this point, the zenith or tippy-top of capitalism making billions upon billions off of every transaction, and large portions of those transactions carrying a guaranteed interest and debt, which further guarantees more returns.
Of course, Marazzi also concludes that bio-power, bio-labor, and bio-capitalism are the new distinctions for ourselves and our surroundings but I don’t see the need to go into that sense some people are still a bit squeamish when it comes to Negri interjecting Foucualt into the economy.

MarxTrek

13 years 1 month ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by MarxTrek on November 5, 2011

With the looting of public funds to curtail an entire financial collapse, "we've seen a process of economic and political concentration and reinforcement of the banks bailed out by the state who have exploited low interest rates to increase profits by directly and almost exclusively investing in the stock market and in state bonds. This has allowed banks to pay back the aid received in the heat of the crisis, but freeing them from any political interference and putting them back into a position of dictating the conditions of recovery" (p.97-98).

S. Artesian

13 years 1 month ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on November 5, 2011

Have to parse this before I can put everything in one succinct response"

MarxTrek

I think the "upswing" or "new upturn" within financial-capitalism is explained within the Conclusion of Aufheben's, "Return of the Crisis (Part II)" though in coupling Aufheben's article with Christian Marazzi's, The Violence of Financial Capitalism it would seem that Aufheben has put too much focus on the possible outcome of Chinese domination, if my memory serves me correct. Marazzi allows for other possibilities and doesn’t seem to interested in predication. So maybe we actually do agree on Aufheben eating those words but not for the same reasons.

Well, if Aufheben is putting its "eggs" in the "China basket" that's one more mistake. Half the population in China is tied to the rural economy. Average plot size is about .5 hectares. China's not going to replace anybody, except maybe Brazil which was supposed to be the pre-China next USA before China became the post-Brazil next USA.

Having just finished Marazzi's text, I found the conclusion in that highly informative and will try to quote and paraphrase it for this discussion. I would just like to take this opportunity to suggest reading Marazzi’s text in its entirety because it dissects the crisis without resorting in suggesting a return Keynesianism.
“In order to save the banking-financial system from collapse with injections of liquidity, public intervention, be it national or supernational, reveals two things: on the one hand, the necessity to plug up with added demand (to prevent a crisis of over production) the surplus value produced in the expansive phase of the cycle through debt, on the access of goods produced in the ascending phase through layoffs and the worsening of living conditions. It is during this phase that we see a selloff of excess produced goods coupled with industrial and bank capital concentrations.

This is nothing but "underconsumption" theory in sophisticated language. Overproduction is not underconsumption.

Overcoming the subprime crisis caused the shift of debt from private to public sectors, but the public debt, increasing vertiginously more than anything else, is the result of the socialization of financial capital made with the taxpayers money and the creation of liquidity by monetary authorities. A kind of communism of capital where the state, i.e. the collectivity, caters to the needs of the “financial soviets,” i.e. banks, insurance companies, investment funds, and hedge funds, imposing a market dictatorship over society”

Either we can find the origins of this process in the relations between capital and wage-labor in the production process, or we can't. If we can't, then we need to pack up our pictures of Marx and go home. I think we can find that origin in those relations.

"In our opinion, the divergence in accumulation rates between developed countries, Asian counties, and new developing countries should be analyzed on the basis of the global form of contemporary capitalism, keeping in mind the strategic roles of transnational companies that directly benefit from the high growth rates of developing countries, repatriating the surplus value realized there to invest it in financial markets, as well as keeping in mind the appearance of new political tools for coordination, intervention, and supernational control, like the G20, the IMF, the World Bank, the WTO, and the central banks of the main regional poles of development. The globalization of capital has internalized peripheral economies, forming the Empire theorized by Negri and Hardt--an empire in which the same logic of exploitation rules, even if articulated in different forms, and where the appropriation of wealth by a transnational capitalist oligarchy dominates. Today, the relationships are inside accumulation processes, every "outside" is already "inside" the process of capitalist growth..."(p.110-111).

Can anyone tell me what that means, concretely? Exactly where have multinational companies repatriated profits to invest in financial markets? US multinational non-financial companies have NOT done this. Period.

"...This is made possible thanks to souring labor conditions, direct and indirect wage compression, precarizing labor and externalization processes of whole segments of production. That is, if the cost of labor is minimized and employment is reduced, profits increase and a part of them are invested in financial markets to guarantee financial rents. The mobility of capital, its orientation towards developing counties with high rates of profit and company delocalization are all processes that have contributed to increasing profits, without, however, triggering a new wave of general prosperity, rather an extreme polarization of incomes. We are witnessing a spiral growth sustained by global rates of accumulation"(p.113).

This is nothing but a retread of old, really old arguments. Where is the empirical data supporting the notion of higher rates of profits in developing countries creating a "shift" in the centers of accumulation, rather than simply contributing to a "general rate of profit" where the existing centers of accumulation are enhanced by investment in the developing countries?

And exactly where has there be a "spiral growth sustained by global rates of accumulation." Look at the post 2003 "recovery"-- and show me the expanding rate of accumulation.

The new phase of accumulation is through financialization of every aspect of the economy. Debt, credit, rent, precarity, and what have you is becoming the key to production of accumulation/surplus-value/profit.

It's hardly a new phase of accumulation, and it's hardly sustained accumulation. It is quite clearly part of the movement of capital between decelerating accumulation, asset liquidation, and contraction.

Maybe this isn’t Aufheben’s “upswing” or “new upturn” as described in “Return of the Crisis” but with Marazzi’s text explains how this crisis created and is creating new accumulation possibilities, and the rising of profits for the financial sector, the financial sector is just, at this point, the zenith or tippy-top of capitalism making billions upon billions off of every transaction, and large portions of those transactions carrying a guaranteed interest and debt, which further guarantees more returns.

Again, "dog bites man." Crisis is supposed to always create new accumulation possibilities.

But exactly where are the new accumulation possibilities, the sustained, expanding accumulation possibilities in the financial sector seeing as how profits of Wall St. investment banks were down in 2008, increased in 2009, declined from 2009- 2010, and are declining again in 2011?

All in all, this reads to me like another iteration on the "inflection point to a new upturn" thesis, that, like all others, is without factual or theoretical basis.

MarxTrek

13 years 1 month ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by MarxTrek on November 6, 2011

I think that Aufheben does a splendid job in explaining its own position regarding "upswing" theories and do it quite meticulously, and coupled with Marazzi "upswing" or crisis as an aspect in a new phase of accumulation, these two ideas of new accumulation or "upswing" has more possibilities than just China in its future, a future more fluid and less based on geopolitics. After having read both "Return of the Crisis" and the Marazzi piece seeing the crisis as just an economic crisis in capitalism and not a total crisis of capitalism, of capitalism meaning the crisis is shaking the very foundations of capitalism (this view puts to much faith in the objective conditions of capital and not enough on the subjective desires and possibilities coming from the working class).

I was to caught up in trying to condense Aufheben and Marazzi's analysis and conclusions that I forgot to include the no one is denying that an economic crisis is ongoing, Aufheben is not denying that after 2007-08 the economy is in crisis.

As for your concerns about the 90s dot.com crash/crisis and the difference between any downturn or crisis in the past when compared to the 2007-08 and ongoing crisis Aufheben explains the economy's ability to absorb the crisis in Part I, section, An Account of the Crisis and its Immediate Causes, "Hence, with hindsight, the dot.com crash and the subsequent recession of 2001-2002, could be seen as little more than a minor correction in what had now become a fifteen year-long economic upswing that had followed the tumultuous years of crisis, class conflict, and economy restructuring of the 1970s and 1980s"(Part I, p.5).

So, its not that the 90s dot.com crash was any different from our crisis today but rather the crash being just an adjustment and capital's ability to remain on an accumulating track despite crisis. These contemporary crises then are part of an accumulation process, no?

Then comes the housing boom and the mortgage backed securities, debt and securitization, and the 2007-08 crash. On the back of the dot.com bubble bursting, we see housing move into the lime light and Greenspan's low interest rates, the deregulation of the banking industry, and debt securities kept everyone in green and profiteering from debt and consumption pushes the economy into massive accumulation, all the while we are too busy being moralists fighting against globalization rather than being economists and staying ahead of the game. Bush's policies were robbing the working class from the future but we accepted the false security of capital's expanse for both classes in the 2000s. Aufheben continues to explain the economic road from the Clinton 90s to the Bush 2000s and the ever expanding economy, maybe reread Part I of "Return of the Crisis" because I am not able to condense it.

Aufheben and Marazzi's point of upswing or new phase of accumulation is not that this accumulation is going on right now within this temporary "downturn" or recession, if that was the case then it would be the magical stealing of money, but this crisis is a bump in the process of the new financial economy devouring the old material Fordist economy and processes of accumulation. Rather, this crisis could be seen as the final stage of digestion of the old economy (overcoming its own created barriers in a process of accumulation).

MarxTrek

13 years 1 month ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by MarxTrek on November 6, 2011

In Aufheben's Conclusion in Part II, they point to this current crisis as a result in the oversupply of loanable money and "Return of the Crisis" traces it all through the 70s up to today. I think that their article provides ample amounts of material examples throughout its article.

But yes this crisis can turn into the demise of capital but that is up to us, the working class to turn the objective conditions into our subjective desires, if not its just another barrier for capital to overcome.

S. Artesian

13 years 1 month ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on November 6, 2011

Well, the 2001-2003 recession was not a dot.com recession and was not caused by "financialization," i.e excess speculation in the financial instruments of "hi-tech" companies.

Overproduction was at work then, driving down the rate of return, and I mean overproduction as Marx describes it in vol 3-- overproduction of the means of production as capital.

I think it's hilarious, and pathetic, that aufheben claims that the 90s [or 1986?] were the beginning of a long term upswing and the "left" is "stuck" in its analysis of the stagnation of the 1970s and 1980s and can't recognize it, when in fact the 90s and beyond only appear as an upturn in comparison to the stagnation of the 70s and 80s. Rates of growth, rates of investment, generalized expansion of the economy with its attendant increases in the measures of social welfare in the 90s were all below the rates for the 60s, and for the 1945-1969 period as a whole.

What has occurred is the transfer of wealth up the social ladder to the top 1/5, and from the top 1/5 to the top 1/10 and from the top 1/10 to the top 1/100.

It's not an "ever expanding economy" as the bourgeoisie know well, which is why they take the actions they do to protect their private property as opposed to accumulating capital.

Aufheben, seriously, has not been paying attention to current events.

Wait and see what happens in 2012 after the deliveries of more containerships, tankers, dry-bulk carriers flood the sinking shipping industry; when earnings growth in the non-financial sector ceases and there is no way for financial institutions to rollover their debts-- get back to me then when unemployment starts to soar, poverty rates skyrocket, about this really being just an inflection point at the beginning of the new upturn.

I'm sure Aufheben will think so. We call that cognitive dissonance-- kind of like what happens in flying saucer cults, when the saucers don't come to whisk you way to planet GaGa at the inflection point of a celestial, cosmic upturn.

MarxTrek

13 years 1 month ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by MarxTrek on November 6, 2011

Awesome response, you are deeply rooted in overproduction, is there an article that explains the crisis in the same in depth manner that Aufbehen built its argument, besides Vol.3? I fear that I am currently reading the holy family and don't want to jump ahead.

MarxTrek

13 years 1 month ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by MarxTrek on November 6, 2011

haha! ok. i will give you a read. compare you and david harvey with aufheben and marazzi. The crisis ain't going anywhere so we will have plenty of time to study it.

MarxTrek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by MarxTrek on November 8, 2011

So it seems that the difference between overproduction crisis view and "upswing" theories are choice of figures and percentages: one taken from the manufacturing non-financial sector and the other from the financial sector, material vs. immaterial. I will have to reread the beginning of Marazzi's piece and compare those stats and percentages with your text in Insurgent Notes to see the disagreement more clearly.

But hey, this is fun!

MarxTrek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by MarxTrek on November 8, 2011

I haven't quite finished the IN text but if my memory serves me correctly Aufheben and Marazzi track the transferring of assets and investments from the American manufacturing sector into the financial sector during the 70s,80s,and 90s and describe how the old economy was devouring itself and looking for new accumulation processes within the financial sector. Does this not begin to bridge gap between overproduction crisis theory and "upswing" theories or manufacturing and financialization becoming one process of accumulation?

S. Artesian

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on November 8, 2011

MarxTrek

I haven't quite finished the IN text but if my memory serves me correctly Aufheben and Marazzi track the transferring of assets and investments from the American manufacturing sector into the financial sector during the 70s,80s,and 90s and describe how the old economy was devouring itself and looking for new accumulation processes within the financial sector. Does this not begin to bridge gap between overproduction crisis theory and "upswing" theories or manufacturing and financialization becoming one process of accumulation?

What new accumulation processes? Devouring itself? Not hardly-- offshoring, yes. Asset-stripping, yes. Transferring wealth up the social ladder, yes. But new accumulation processes as opposed to the old accumulation processes of exchanging capital with wage-labor? the means of production organized as private property with labor power organized as a commodity? What new accumulation processes are generated by the financial sector that don't involve the value/devaluation identity?

The financial history is derivative, completely, from the changing ratios of the components of capital acccumulation.

Blasto

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Blasto on November 8, 2011

S. Artesian

I think it's hilarious, and pathetic, that aufheben claims that the 90s [or 1986?] were the beginning of a long term upswing and the "left" is "stuck" in its analysis of the stagnation of the 1970s and 1980s and can't recognize it, when in fact the 90s and beyond only appear as an upturn in comparison to the stagnation of the 70s and 80s. Rates of growth, rates of investment, generalized expansion of the economy with its attendant increases in the measures of social welfare in the 90s were all below the rates for the 60s, and for the 1945-1969 period as a whole.

What has occurred is the transfer of wealth up the social ladder to the top 1/5, and from the top 1/5 to the top 1/10 and from the top 1/10 to the top 1/100.

It's not an "ever expanding economy" as the bourgeoisie know well, which is why they take the actions they do to protect their private property as opposed to accumulating capital.

Aufheben, seriously, has not been paying attention to current events.

While GDP hides a multitude of sins, there are not many other usable yardsticks about, so....

Using contemporary $ value:

Global GDP
1960 = $1.248 trillion
1970 = $2.879 trillion
1980 = $10.985 trillion
1990 = $21.90 trillion
2000 = $32.213 trillion
2010 = $63.044 trillion

Global GDP per capita (contemporary $ value)
1960 = $445
1970 = $781
1980 = $2477
1990 = $4154
2000 = $5298
2010 = $9216

The rise in Global average life expectancy:
1960 = 52.6
1970 = 59.3
1980 = 62.9
1990 = 65.4
2000 = 67.2
2010 = 69.4

Child mortality (per 1000 live births - I can't find these figures for 1960)
1970 = 101.57
1980 = 76.7
1990 = 62.37
2000 = 52.04
2010 = 41
In the same period, mortality rates for children under five had fallen by almost 2/3.

So it is not accurate to say that wealth has simply been transferred upstairs. It is true that in the West, low-end wages have been suppressed for the last 30 years (edit: actually it been 40 years) The 'middle' has seen steady gains. The top has gone off the scale. What has happened can be more realistically characterised as economic growth has not been transferred into gains for the working class in the West. That says nothing about the state of capitalism, more about the defeat of the working class.

The story is quite different in China where poverty has fallen dramatically. In India, people living below the poverty line dropped from 55% in 1974 to 27.5% in 2004. Child mortality in India has fallen by more than two thirds in the same period, while in China it has fallen by almost three quarters.

Looks to me like globally the economy it has been racing along quite nicely (infact global GDP growth in 2010 was at it highest point since 2003). It's a mistake to take a euro-centric view. That horse pottered out of the stable in the early 1980s when China de-walled, and finally bolted in the early 1990s when India followed suit.

So while capitalism is booming (the wealthy just keep on getting wealthier) what is very true is the ongoing post-war gains by the Western working class stalled with the defeats in late sixties. If anyone thinks '68 isn't utterly significant, think again.

[EDIT: millenium bug - forgot year 2000 figures - now in]

S. Artesian

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on November 9, 2011

There are many, many other yardsticks. And for one, we might adjust those numbers for inflation since 1960. Just for starters.... IIRC, I think that deflator is pretty significant.

The human welfare statistics certainly show improvement, except... except the last time I checked the millennium development goals established by the UN [to be met by 2015] are unlikely to be achieved in country after country in Africa, and for women in country after country around the world.

Nobody has claimed capitalism hasn't grown, or that capital has ceased accumulating. However rates of growth in the US, Central and South America have slowed, post 1969. Not for nothing is the 1980s known as the "lost decade" in Latin America. Living standards, wage rates, etc. for workers in Chile, Argentina, Uruguay have never recovered, and are unlikely to do so under capitalism

Japan's growth since the 1990 has been basically zero.

The point being that Aufheben's claim that this is an inflection point for a new upturn is so 180 degrees out of phase with reality that it's crackpot theorizing.

One could just as surely take the numbers for the growth in containerized freight trade and point to the consistent growth in TEU [twenty foot equivalent unit] shipments since 1960, or the massive new tonnage being brought on line in the shipping industry lines [container, tanker, and dry bulk] and say that things are moving along just swimmingly-- until you get to the actual decline in trade, in container shipments in 2009; the oversupply of shipping capacity that is driving rates below break even points.

Yes, rate of growth in 2010 was the highest since 2003, since 2010 was a partial recovery from the 2009 trough. Doesn't prove anything, does it?

What your graph does show however is the divergence of incomes, the growing gap between the wealthier and the poorer-- the expanding inequality. This has been noticeably severe in the US.

The point you make that I think is accurate, and an important correction to what I stated earlier, is that such wealth as has been produced as been aggrandized more heavily by the wealthy [and as personal wealth] than in previous decades.

Blasto

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Blasto on November 9, 2011

S. Artesian

There are many, many other yardsticks. And for one, we might adjust those numbers for inflation since 1960. Just for starters.... IIRC, I think that deflator is pretty significant.

That is a good point and I should have done that otherwise the figures look crazy. Cumulative global inflation is hard to figure out at this time of night, but inflation the US is actually fairly close and cumulative US inflation is easy to find.. I'll let the reader figure the rest. As you'll see, growth consistently, but not evenly, outstrips inflation.

EDIT : Have removed the dodgy mental maths here - I have posted properly calculated figures in a later post!

S. Artesian

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on November 9, 2011

I have to question your sources. The World Bank tables for global GDP, calculated in constant year 2000 dollars show the 1991-2000 growth at 31% and 2001-2010 growth at 26%.

I'll go back and check the archives for the pre 1990 data, but I think it will show the 1981-1990 growth below that of the 1990s, and below the post-WW2 averages.

The question is, what constitutes an "inflection point" for a "long upturn"?

S. Artesian

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on November 9, 2011

Couldn't find the data on the WB site, but the IMF had data from which real GDP growth rates can be determined:

Shows 1971-1980 44% growth; 1981-1990 37% growth. I find the 1981-1990 figure tough to accept given the slow growth in the US, the harsh downturns in Mexico, Central and South America.

Still, going from 44% growth 1971-1980 to 26% growth 2001-2010 does not strike me as marking a "long upturn."

Blasto

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Blasto on November 9, 2011

All my figures are from the World Bank. As I said in my last post, the second set of figures were a bit rough (some mental maths late at night). In the first post they are directly quoted from the World Bank.

Ignore my rough calculations though - here's the same decade-end figures using a GDP deflator, so values shown are based on what they would be worth compared to GDP in 2010 (in contemporary dollars). These figures show the GDP for that particular year, not the cumulative GDP for the decade.

1960 = $8 trillion
1970 = $13.10 trillion
1980 = $25.5 trillion
1990 = $33.7 trillion
2000 = $40.3 trillion
2010 = $63.044 trillion

I hope that is clearer.

I think there is a perception among capitalists that growth is infinite (at least in the foreseeable future). Most people here would disagree, but not necessarily because of some fatal flaw in its 'tendencies', but because it cannot reconcile class interests*. In that sense the income graph is far more insightful than searching for signs of capitalism's imminent self-destruction. Such 'tendencies' are continually defied because it is dynamic, innovative and adaptive. Even the current crisis in Europe is only potentially fatal because it is exposing capitalism to a massive social opposition. Capitalists can clearly resolve the economic crisis. They cannot necessarily solve the social one. That is precisely what is being played out in Greece.

* edit - and these interests are not only about the share of wealth, but quality of life, the environment, etc

MarxTrek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by MarxTrek on November 9, 2011

Ok, well someone went and got us some new facts and figures to work with in our discussion, and its very interesting that these stats and figures show the complete opposite to S.Artesian's facts and stats. Could the three of us attempt to explain the difference in numbers (or are we dealing with two worlds with two different capitalisms)?

I am not sure here but is there a different result if you are to look at the numbers and percentages regarding accumulation in manufacturing or the this PPE index as opposed to the WB numbers of the GDP which seems to be the collective representation of accumulation for entire nations?

someone needs to change their perspective or we need to get to the bottom of this.

MarxTrek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by MarxTrek on November 9, 2011

I think there is a perception among capitalists that growth is infinite (at least in the foreseeable future). Most people here would disagree, but not necessarily because of some fatal flaw in its 'tendencies', but because it [capital] cannot reconcile class interests*. In that sense the income graph is far more insightful than searching for signs of capitalism's imminent self-destruction. Such 'tendencies' are continually defied because it is dynamic, innovative and adaptive. Even the current crisis in Europe is only potentially fatal because it is exposing capitalism to a massive social opposition. Capitalists can clearly resolve the economic crisis. They cannot necessarily solve the social one. That is precisely what is being played out in Greece.

Thank you for recognizing that its the working class that is the creator of wealth and the body able to create revolution!

S. Artesian

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on November 9, 2011

I don't utilize GDP figures very much because I don't think they really tell us anything, other than in the long run a) capitalism expands until it doesn't b) we're all dead.

The World Bank figures might be a little more helpful if we adjust for population and inflation, which the WB does for the period after 1970 with its data on GNP per capita in constant year 2000 dollars.

That data shows growth for:

1970-1979 at 20.6%
1980-1989 at 14.3%
1990-1999 at 11.8%
2000-2009 at 10.7%

So I don't think there's much support that this is an "inflection point" in a "long upturn" that has lasted 15 years.

I am certainly not one to argue against the fact that capital grows, expands, accumulates, and increases output, and can even increase the development of productive forces. Indeed, I argue that it can and does, and that's what overproduction is: the overproduction of the means of production as capital beyond the ability to exploit labor-power at a sufficient intensity to offset declining profitability.

This in turn leads to the overall slowing of growth, attacks on wages and living standards, the reallocation of wealth up the social ladder, and the skewing of income portions toward the wealthier.

Aufheben's argument is that we are in the middle of a "long upturn." I don't know how one can characterize the period from 1996 on as a long upturn, unless one accepts that any rate of growth, any increase in the "gross" measures of GDP, GNI represent an upturn.

Blasto

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Blasto on November 9, 2011

Say start with a $10 per capita global economy

1970-1979 at 20.6% = $12.06
1980-1989 at 14.3% = $13.78
1990-1999 at 11.8% = $15.41
2000-2009 at 10.7% = $17.06

So in real terms (if this were communism) everybody would be 70% wealthier today than in 1970.

Obviously example $ figures, but your % figures. Nothing too exciting happening there really, just fairly steady growth, and that is deflated economic growth per capita after considering ever an accelerating population growth (but its not as if wealth creation or accumulation is spread out like smarties anyway).

MarxTrek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by MarxTrek on November 9, 2011

True per capita growth is complete nonsensical in attempting to judge people's well being within any nation. Per capita is not an accurate representation of our individual well-being but it seems to be an indicator in regards to wealth generated. Also, with inflation added into the mix, well from an American point of view, that doesn't really translate into being better off today than in the 70s. Here in my home town there is a local campaign to raise the minimum hourly wage to $10.37 (or something) and statistically, with inflation added into the calculations, this wage only gets us back to the standards of 1968.

So yes, Capital has been sucking the blood of the worker and paying us less than what "we deserve" for 30 some years and it is an indication of Capital attempting to squeeze the worker, suppress wages; but with everything that Aufheben, Marazzi, and now Blasto has provided, is the suppression of wages and this crisis a sign solely of overproduction and a max critical for capitalist accumulation, or is the suppression of wages and the breaking of the unions in the 70s and 80s, and the proliferation of financing and credit a new round of class re-composition, a new phase of accumulation, and battles won by capitalism in this class war?

Is capitalism the motor of accumulation or is it the worker who begrudgingly provides the ability to accumulate?

MarxTrek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by MarxTrek on November 9, 2011

Again, I am not an economist but it seems that the breaking down of American manufacturing, the rapid growth of the service sector, and the advance of the financial sector, finance being Capital's ability to jump over the barrier of a slowing down of the "real economy", is the state we are in today. Therefore it would make sense that the PPE index and other strictly material sectors are in decline or stagnate because American industry is no longer an epicenter of accumulation, whereas finance is.

S. Artesian

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on November 10, 2011

Blasto

Say start with a $10 per capita global economy

1970-1979 at 20.6% = $12.06
1980-1989 at 14.3% = $13.78
1990-1999 at 11.8% = $15.41
2000-2009 at 10.7% = $17.06

So in real terms (if this were communism) everybody would be 70% wealthier today than in 1970.

Obviously example $ figures, but your % figures. Nothing too exciting happening there really, just fairly steady growth, and that is deflated economic growth per capita after considering ever an accelerating population growth (but its not as if wealth creation or accumulation is spread out like smarties anyway).

I think what this shows is a steady decline in the ratio, the rate of growth over the years, and for capitalism rate, ratio is everything. Capital is only capital that it can expand, and the rate of the expansion is a reflection of overall profitability.

GDP per capita isn't being used to indicate anything about welfare, distribution, etc. The per capita adjustment is simply to account for a growing population, that's all. A capital that expands by 20% over its original mass in 20 years is not expanding at all relative to population if that population increases by the same amount.

The issue is: on what basis can we describe the "2 decades" aufheben claims is a new upswing as a 20 year upswing, when the rate growth has declined over the 2 decades; when in fact the recovery from the 2001-2003 recession globally was weak; and when the 2007-2009 recession was the most severe since the Great Depression and the recovery, in terms of income, employment and output has been significantly weaker than the recovery from previous contractions?

Marx-Trek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Marx-Trek on November 13, 2011

So, your classical Marxist take on the declining profit rate and overproduction has interested me and my skeptical friends of the Negrian take on bio-capitalism, but I am rereading the Marazzi piece, The Violence of Financial Capitalism Chapter 1. The Becoming of Crisis, Chapter 2. Financial Logics, and Chapter 3. On the Becoming-Rent of Profit and Marazzi addresses the difference between today's crisis and the regional crises of the resent past; the difference being that in the past having a regional crisis (the less)global capitalism was able to stave off any global breakdown through other regions financing the US during crisis but today with the complete interconnectedness of economies the very expanse itself was a blow to global capital.

They then go on and write about the break up of Fordism and the financialization of the global economy and how even GM, a company representing the classic accumulation through production of material things and receiving a profit at cycles end, has even shifted its way of profit accumulation through credit and the financing.

In relation to Aufheben, Marazzi like Aufheben conclude that the West as a fixture at the top is slowly declining but accumulation is not. Whether we all have to learn Chinese or not, well I am not a palm reader, but then again America was once upon a time a little colony...

S. Artesian

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on November 14, 2011

They then go on and write about the break up of Fordism and the financialization of the global economy and how even GM, a company representing the classic accumulation through production of material things and receiving a profit at cycles end, has even shifted its way of profit accumulation through credit and the financing.

They're a little behind the times, since 1) "financialization" of major US production industries really decelerated after the 2001-2003 recession. By that I mean the dependence on US production industries for bank financing tumbled, with cash reserves and assets accumulating to highs and bank debt rates slowing. In the US the banks are now a source of less than 1/3 or industry financing. In the EU, I think the number is closer to 80% 2) GM's NMA [new model accumulation] didn't exactly work out, did it? GM's old model accumulation-- reduced fixed assets, sell off units, reduce employment, let the workers fund the benefit portion of wages directly, that seems to be their New NMA-- maybe not Fordism [a really, really, stupid term] but maybe "Fordism lite."

And this bit about "this crisis being different because in the past capitalism could always push the crisis off on other areas" gets run up the flagpole as something brand new every time there's an economic contraction. This tired old argument has been primped and pimped out ever since Rosa's Accumulation of Capital.

There is no "new" in this NMA, and really nothing new in the Negri iteration.

Marx-Trek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Marx-Trek on November 15, 2011

Nothing new about a global financial crisis vs. regional crisis used to keep certain ways to divert a global crisis?

Nothing new with debt and credit fueled mortgage backed securities and housing markets in the US going up and up all funded by such a large amount of the debt/credit cycle as getting passed the stagnate growth within Fordist era?

Nothing new with the rise in Chinese economic power and the US all of a sudden scrambling to pay its debts?

Maybe nothing new with the capitalist looting of public monies to pay for things but it sure looks like all the public money (capital) that was taken by the banking industry was not used to shore up easy lending money and kick start the economy but was rather held onto for future capital investments, looks like a somewhat new process of accumulation to me.

Not because public money has never been given to capitalist projects before but because the vast amount of given money, with zero interest, wasn't dumped into the system but was held onto and then given back as to guarantee no nationalization of the banking industry here in the US.

S. Artesian

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on November 17, 2011

What is the "nothing" in this "nothing new model accumulation" is precisely that-- accumulation. It is the same old, same old accumulation of capital, transformation of the relations between living and dead labor, between the means of production constituted as capital, and labor-power organized as a commodity that has triggered this latest disruption.

It's the same old overproduction, declining profitability, inability to exploit labor at a sufficient intensity to offset the decline that is at the core of-- not just the crisis, but the expansion of asset-backed securities, CDOs, etc. That's what's not new in the "new model accumulation."

The US scrambling to pay its debts? You mean the US Treasury? Not hardly-- the bondholders haven't gotten around to attacking that debt yet, and I don't think they really want to.

Marx-Trek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Marx-Trek on November 17, 2011

So simply put, either there is something unique/different/extra with emergence of finance-capitalism from the 1960/70s and how accumulation occurs or there is nothing interesting/extra/different with capital accumulation going on?

I do not think that any of the articles/theories/prophecies we have been discussing deny the classic understanding of production/consumption/accumulation cycles. Rather, these articles are stating that there is something going on within the whole process and that new methods for accumulation are being created, there is not anything profound being said here but its important to see how new processes of accumulation are occuring in order to better combat capital as workers wanting to no longer be workers.

S. Artesian

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on November 18, 2011

Well, what are the new methods for accumulation. Tell me how the use of asset-backed-securities constitutes a new mode of accumulation, and not simply a mechanism for apportioning already accumulated value?

Marx-Trek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Marx-Trek on November 25, 2011

I think the explosion of credit supported consumption and the resulting crisis including all that backed securities, etc... has transformed the American worker, the world consumer into a credit/debt worker producing debt which then makes capital/money/profit/surplus value, etc...

S. Artesian

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on November 25, 2011

Marx-Trek

I think the explosion of credit supported consumption and the resulting crisis including all that backed securities, etc... has transformed the American worker, the world consumer into a credit/debt worker producing debt which then makes capital/money/profit/surplus value, etc...

Wow. That's a lot packed into once sentence. First, the "American worker" does not provide the bulk of consumption. The top 20% account for 40% of all consumption.

Secondly, it's a tautology to say the US worker is a "credit/debt worker producing debt.." and it's almost impossible to understand what you mean by the credit/debt worker creating "capital/money/profit/surplus value." Do you mean that consumption now produces surplus value? If so, the bourgeoisie have stumbled on something akin to cold fusion and/or the perpetual motion machine.

Exactly how does that work? A US worker takes out a mortgage to purchase a house; then several years later takes cash out of that house, essentially providing a partial liquidation, by taking on a 2nd mortgage, or a credit line, or a home equity loan which [I think] amounted to about 40% (?) of the mortgage activity after 2005 [again, can't remember the specifics] and that process creates surplus value? Where? How?

Marx-Trek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Marx-Trek on November 26, 2011

Workers fight for housing rights and affordable housing in the US, communism does not happen and capitalism concedes to workers, housing rights and affordable housing happens, real estate and banks get involved in a "new" emerging market for cheap housing, loans and money that people don't have but say they will pay it back drives the market, deregulation of investment and lenders happens over the past 30,40,50 years, more loans, more houses, the bubble grows, banks make a bunch of profit/surplus-value/money off this credit lending loans and then this generates bundling and more profit/surplus-value to complete cycle...

Then we have credit card companies same banks and investors as the housing market, workers, student-worker, poor-workers get credit, their credit builds and builds, and people pay back interests but not enough, it grows and grows, people are just like the banks with their toxic assets....people don't get bailed out, plus credit card companies make their money off of these poor students and poor workers. The bulk of profit comes from poor-workers spending and getting into debt because its profitable and the only means of subsistence, the banks wouldn't do it if it wasn't profitable. Wages paid to workers who then consume to complete the cycle of profit/surplus-value accumulation isn't enough for capitalism to get its returns, the unions are crushed and workers lose real wages, so in order to overcome this stagnate rate of profit, credit and easy to get credit cards and loans, the toxic assets generate the bubbles, it grows and grows. This gets us back to the housing market, people buy houses, take out loans, mortgages, second mortgages, and banks and investors start bundling and creating all those bonds, securities, etc...feeding off the loans and credit card consumption of workers, etc...these securities, swaps, and the lot are not funny money but actually created off the workers and people who loaned money to buy things, all things, if there isn't a connection then its all fake.

Here is the "new" markets that opened up after WWII and then kicked into high gear through credit and debt. Houses bought by vets, then by blacks, then by any and all loaners of money, and the financial markets ate it all up.

crisis hits...or crisis is now recognized as a constant (how many crisis can happen one after another, decade after decade, and now it seems year after year, before it is just accepted as a constant crisis?)

Government money is pumped into the market, done so by the republican free marketeers, nothing happens, crisis unfolds, nationalization of banks, again done so by the deregulation junkies at their highest, not that politics really matters in the end, and nothing really happens the crisis continues, and uncomprehending amount of money is given to the one's that managed the crisis by both republicans and democrats and the bankers take it and do nothing, the banks do not lend, the banks insure that this government injection is just a cushion and the banks generate enough money back through the market and repay the bailout money to insure no left-liberal could come in and become the next "real"or perceived FDR or a social-democrat, and on top of that the money was given at zero percent interest rate, banks need to profit not the government because if the government profits then there is enough capital to invest in say schools, healthcare, and welfare and maybe one day a citizen's income.

People get foreclosed on, people get evicted, people lose jobs, people go further into debt, and borrowing money is the only option, which isn't an option. So yes, the old slash and burn to increase revenue is happening, of course its happening.

Now the rock stars of communist theory and postmodern leftist political-economists are talking about the importance of rent and Marx's manuscripts of 1844. Rent or debt and credit-slavery is the new emerging market in crisis.

I think or I am completely lost and I have just convinced myself that orthodox or classical Marxist economic theory is dated and needs a bit of updating but not replacing.

Marx-Trek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Marx-Trek on November 26, 2011

As someone pointed out earlier and I will ask again, where is the worker in all your theory besides just being the constant victim and loser rather than part of the dialectical struggle (worker vs. capital)?

S. Artesian

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on November 26, 2011

Where's the worker in whose theory? My "theory"? I'm not presenting a theory. I'm presenting a historical analysis of what capitalism does, why it does it, what it compels the classes which constituted the capital relationship to do.

Where is the worker? Nowhere. Where are the workers, as a class? Everywhere. Confronting the conditions of their labor in and out of the workplace. Workers don't cause, by an act of conscious will, what Marx referred to as crisis in capitalism. Capitalism causes the crisis through the terms of value production. The class of workers is the source of that value production and thus "cause" a crisis by that fact.

But crisis is not overthrow, not abolition. Overthrow and abolition are immanent in capital, but require appropriation, social action. So where are the workers? In the streets in Greece, for one; moving from limited "general" strike to :limited" general strike.

Your "theory"-- your description of current capitalism-- comes down to nothing but another iteration of underconsumption theory:

Wages paid to workers who then consume to complete the cycle of profit/surplus-value accumulation isn't enough for capitalism to get its returns, the unions are crushed and workers lose real wages, so in order to overcome this stagnate rate of profit, credit and easy to get credit cards and loans, the toxic assets generate the bubbles, it grows and grows.

That's what it comes down to-- all the rock stars with all their "rent" theories [by and large the weakest, most problematic, and historically inaccurate portion of Marx's analysis] labor mightily back and forth between renter and rentier, creditor and debtor, and all they bring forth is one more trip down underconsumptionist lane.

Your account of the expansion of capitalism after WW2 is simply not historically and/or theoretically accurate.

Yes, cheaper housing existed. No it did not determine capitalist accumulation; it was derivative of capitalist accumulation. Yes, some African-Americans bought home. No, there was nothing in this that determined the economic status of African-Americans; rather it was derivative of the movement of African-Americans into the industrial labor force.

Marx-Trek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Marx-Trek on November 26, 2011

Underconsumption in a period that saw great increases in consumption during the post-war years and then more consumption through credit, loans, and the rest?

I thought i was suggesting that the crisis is was brought on by the financialization of the economy and the ever more interconnectedness of global capital and how the housing market played a pretty big role in all that, since banks and investor were making unbelievable profits off it all. And for the housing market, people buying houses they couldn't afford but did so anyways because they were told that if they buy a house they have successfully bought their ticket out of the working class and into the (fictitious) middle class, after all houses were suppose to make money not make you broke.

Capitalism causes the crisis through the terms of value production. The class of workers is the source of that value production and thus "cause" a crisis by that fact.

So then what are your conclusions on value production within the housing market?

So the post-war years did not usher in a period of growth, increase in production, and consumption?

As for African Americans with the onsite of industrial agriculture American history saw huge mass migrations from the south into the west and northeast city centers. African American were driven off the land and into the parts of the industrial sector, it was a hard fight to get in, and then you see the dismantling of American industry and the african american working class had a compounded problem of ghettoization and loss of urban industrial jobs through racism and classism.

But housing since the end of WWII has been one of the key markets and cultural signs of America.

Are you suggesting that housing was not a site of exploitation?

Is value accumulation only happening within factory walls and the production of tractors, cars, planes, bombs, and refrigerators? Back to the PPE index, the GDP, and the import and export trade deficits?

Though trade deficits play an interesting role in the American ecnomy.

Just watched an interesting economic documentary about the federal debt, though it had some underpinnings of libertarianism, that pointed out that the US threatened Britian back during the Suez Canal crisis that the US would pull its holdings in British bonds and that financial warfare was the end of the British empire.

S. Artesian

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on November 27, 2011

Marx-Trek

Underconsumption in a period that saw great increases in consumption during the post-war years and then more consumption through credit, loans, and the rest?

I cited what you wrote. Certainly there were great increases in consumption in the post-war years. That's kind of what post-war entails as what the war itself does is restore profitability.

If we go back to the Aufheben article [remember that?] their point was that the "left" was stuck in the 1970s and 1980s with its analysis of "stagnant" capitalism; and that this current point is an "inflection point" marking a new phase in the "long upturn" that has been ongoing for nearly two decades.

Clearly Aufheben recognizes that the "post-war" period is not one of uniform continuous growth. There was the 1945-1969/70 period, and then the post 1970 period. There was a decline in rates of growth, rates of investment, and rates of return on investment after 1970.

Aufheben argues that period of decline ended in the 1990s. Rates of growth, investment, and return on investment in the US did improve after 1993-- peaking in the late 90s, with economy crashing into recession in 2001. The recovery 2003-2007 in terms of rates of growth, rates of investment, increases in employment, etc. was the weakest of the post-war period. And now we have the most severe contraction, with "the greatest decline in living standards since the Great Depression" [Mervyn King, governor of the Bank of England], and we're supposed to believe that this is an inflection point in a "long upturn"?

I thought i was suggesting that the crisis is was brought on by the financialization of the economy and the ever more interconnectedness of global capital and how the housing market played a pretty big role in all that,

Honestly, I don't know what "financialization of the economy and ever more interconnectedness of global capital" means as far as "bringing on a crisis." By what mechanism do those facets cause a crisis in capital? Are we going to get another iteration of Minsky's theory of excess? Greenspan's "irrational exuberance"?

How does the "global interconnectedness of capital" bring on a crisis as a result simply of its global interconnections? Does that mean if McDonald's, Coca Cola, Citibank didn't have global markets, global outlets, global production sites, there wouldn't be a crisis? Does that mean that because they do have global connections, therefore global connections cause the crisis? That's just nonsense. Global connections have been integral to capitalism for 170 years.

So then what are your conclusions on value production within the housing market?

Same as my conclusion on value production in the automobile market. The market itself is derivative, determined by the exploitation of the labor in the production of the commodity. The actual sale represents a moment in the realization of that value.

So the post-war years did not usher in a period of growth, increase in production, and consumption?

Of course they did. See above. I want to know what's "new" in this? What's the new mode of accumulation? Is it based in the exploitation of labor as labor, in production? Or is it based on some new relationship, and credit, debt, speculation, flim-flam, etc do not count as new relationships for capital, nor do they amount to a new mode of production.

As for African Americans with the onsite of industrial agriculture American history saw huge mass migrations from the south into the west and northeast city centers. African American were driven off the land and into the parts of the industrial sector, it was a hard fight to get in, and then you see the dismantling of American industry and the african american working class had a compounded problem of ghettoization and loss of urban industrial jobs through racism and classism.

Yes. but that didn't happen all at once. Part of it happened in the 1945-1969 upturn; a different part has happened in the "long slowdown" since app 1971. But what part of it happened in the supposed "long upturn" since 1990?

Are you suggesting that housing was not a site of exploitation?

See above remark about autos. Do you think purchasing an automobile is a site of exploitation? Is the purchase a site of value production? The purchase, the ability to purchase, is derivative of the success [or lack thereof] capital has in exploiting labor profitably enough.

I

s value accumulation only happening within factory walls and the production of tractors, cars, planes, bombs, and refrigerators? Back to the PPE index, the GDP, and the import and export trade deficits?

Value production does not occur through the generation of financial instruments. Securitization of mortgages does not amount to the accumulation of value.

Marx-Trek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Marx-Trek on November 28, 2011

Do you think purchasing an automobile is a site of exploitation? Is the purchase a site of value production? The purchase, the ability to purchase, is derivative of the success [or lack thereof] capital has in exploiting labor profitably enough.

Well that would just be silly to suggest that buying something outright is exploitation. I am suggesting that through financialization newer methods of purchase has been added at the end of the realization of value and profit/surplus-value, in the sale and reselling of a commodity to the consumer-working class. Not only do we pay for something outright we continue to pay for it through credit, loans, and interest payment that seem to never stop a continuation of payment. I am also suggesting that it isn't going to stop because nothing has been changed in regards to people having to over extend themselves in order to live in 2011 and beyond. What has changed for the working class today in comparison to the working class in say early and mid 1900s is that we are no longer working ourselves to stay afloat but are now wokring ourselves to keep up. Through credit the working class can live beyond its means not because it has to but because it must. Its just not realistic to tell a working class family to either eat, but clothes, or pay the energy bill, so in comes credit.

The housing market is a site of exploitation and extraction of surplus-value on the living of life. Commodities are sold to realize exchange-value and complete the cycle of value accumulation but with the financial changes over the past 30 or so years, a lot has changed and more value accumulation has occurred, accumulation of capital, money is that liquid form, which can in turn make more capital. And of course, that within capitalism capital is only interested in creating more value and any market is just a derivative or the means to which capital is realized.

Aufheben's article still seems to explain this crisis and its history more clearly than any other explaination, including your own article that has been linked, read, and i liked it but it seems to focused on stats like The Economist and fixated on the manufacturing end of things. Maybe I am missing something.

Marx-Trek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Marx-Trek on November 28, 2011

sorry, I meant to say that the working class does not choose to live beyond its own means because it wants to but because it must. Either we become moralists and say that our class must become thrifty but that ignores reality that is at play here.

S. Artesian

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on November 28, 2011

Aufheben's article still seems to explain this crisis and its history more clearly than any other explaination, including your own article that has been linked, read, and i liked it but it seems to focused on stats like The Economist and fixated on the manufacturing end of things. Maybe I am missing something.

I think you are: the part where they claim this is a new inflection point in a "long upturn." Where's the new upturn?

Marx-Trek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Marx-Trek on November 30, 2011

I think it was Blasto, or the other person who commented on here who used stats, percentages, and such which showed a slow and steady up swing or "long upturn" in regards to both development and accumulation. There seems to be two different stats going on here in our discussion and I think that your concentration on manufacturing, the PPE, etc... in the west does conclude a decline in the rate of profit, but there are also supporting arguments for growth.

What I find convincing about the Aufheben article, Marazzi's text, and the other person's comments and figures on this thread is that it takes into consideration the decline within manufacturing yet explores the emergence of new markets and new forms of accumulation of surplus value/profit. After all new markets or new methods of production, more international, financialized, or otherwise, are only Capital's methods in chasing surplus-value and profits. If Capital could accumulate in only making envelops, then that is all that would be produced under capitalist command.

S. Artesian

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on November 30, 2011

What was shown, once you adjust his GDP figures [and that was the marker that was used] is a persistent deceleration in the rates of growth of GDP per capita.

If you look at capital investment, you see the gross amounts rising, you see the rate of growth contracting. Capitalism is all about rate, proportion, ratio.

Marx-Trek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Marx-Trek on December 1, 2011

yes, well I also recall blasto arguing that that was accounted for and continued to show a slow and steady growth which seems to say the opposite of your conclusions.

I do not think that the analysis of growth, however slow or steady, or decline, no matter how drastic of steady is of the up most importance. Rather, I see the activities of the working-class, our activities against capitalist command to be more interesting, and so within Aufheben's analysis and Marazzi's texts there is more focus on the activities of the working class. We are given more breathing room and more possibilities in those analyses. I am not suggesting that those texts paint a prettier picture but they have a more dynamic view of workers vs. capital.

As for the "long upturn", I did not take from Aufheben that they are denying a crisis. Rather, I see that Aufheben is seeing the crisis as a crisis within accumulation not of capitalism being able to accumulate.

Of course all stats and ratios show a decline of accumulation after they are adjusted, what does that even mean.

But then again, I am not married to the idea of a "long upturn", but this discussion has reminded me of the anti-globalization days where people were discussing the evils and wrongs of it morally but not economically. We were reactionary in responding to globalization in the early 2000s. We argued that globalization was gonna ruin so many lives and not prove to be profitable but they had stats and figures that showed growth and a rising standard of living for people. A lot of people missed the point, it doesn't matter if capital provides us with a better standard of living when opposing capital's command and the imposition of work. We should be resisting capitalism because of the position it puts us in relation to capital and the capitalists. It does not matter if we get better things and a better standard of living when our fight is against the relationship within capital.

Its kinda the same thing here, decline in the profit rate, falling rates in accumulation, or crisis theory just sees the cyclical patterns of capitalism where everything is bad and upswing theories seem more focused on the relationship between worker and capital,

S. Artesian

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on December 2, 2011

I'm not arguing good and bad. I'm arguing for some historical accuracy.

There was a long upturn-- 1945 to 1969. There has been a persistent deceleration of capitalism, no matter how you measure it since that time.

What constitutes the long upturn? That was the original issue I raised. That is Aufheben's claim. "New inflection point in a long upturn" right?

Where do we see that since 2001, with the post 2003 recovery for the advanced capitalist countries being the weakest in the post-ww2 era? With the Asian NIE's suffering reduced rates of growth?

Do we see a new upturn in Africa? In the Mideast? China?-- sure everybody thinks China is the next......the next what? US? the next EU? [Hey remember all that baloney about how the US went to war with Iraq to prevent it from pricing its oil in euros? How the US wants to go to war with Iran because it is pricing its oil in euros? Have to laugh about that one].

it doesn't matter if capital provides us with a better standard of living when opposing capital's command and the imposition of work.

Except that's not the issue. The issue is that in fact it does matter when capital attacks the living standards, transfers greater portions of the produced wealth to small portions of the elite. Look around-- that's why people are in the streets.

Marx-Trek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Marx-Trek on December 2, 2011

OK, we seem to misrepresenting each other and drawing lines of disagreement from each other posts that seem to not be all that relevant as this discussion keeps on spiraling.

Of course it matters when capital: cuts public budgets, bails out private corporations with public funds, cuts wages (directly or indirectly through policies and inflation), and creates unemployment. It hurts us all.

I don't believe I ever suggested that wage reduction, firings, and other methods of capital reigning in its flow of liquid cash doesn't happen, nor do I remember suggesting that under-consumption theory was the key to understanding the current crisis. Also, I don't remember denying that manufacturing in the West has been destroyed and moved to the South and East and with it the decline in accumulation and growth. You are probably right on with all that and I see that you are well read on what you are proposing. I agree with you because I have no reason to disagree.

We seem to differ in regards to the importance and impact of the financial and credit industries which Aufheben's article delves deep into, and Marazzi's, The Violence of Financial Capitalism goes further in describing how "fictitious" financial capital is a "new" method of accumulation within the crisis and not fictitious at all. Within this description and analysis of the history of deregulation and globalization emerges the possibility of Aufheben's "long upturn theory". To be fair you seem to always shy away from discussing the financial and credit industries.

I just started reading David Harvey's, The Enigma of Capital and so far he seems to be combing both of our positions and synthesizing them.

Here is my thought on Aufheben's "upturn theory", the credit industry and the looting of public funds to rescue and secure liquidity for investment industry could be an indication of continued growth, accumulation of wealth, and the continuation of neoliberal policies laid down since the end of the 60s onto the present shows an upward trend not a downward trend. Yes there are crises within this process, as history shows, and there have been downturns but these downturns are within an upturn. I think that Aufheben even suggested these and shows it through graphs and examples. Its like a small deep on the ride up, the deep is still higher than accumulation in the past before this whole process.

Now either that is totally wrong and I need to asses my own position and check my facts but even if we were to simplify it down to a general statement being made by every socio-economic commentator in the world, "the disparity between the rich and poor today is more than it has ever been", there seems to be something to the mystery of rich getting richer while we all downturn. Now either this is because capital is crushing labor power and taking back surplus-value through wage reductions, or capital is increasing production of surplus-value through more efficient means, or both and capital through neoliberal policies is crushing us and compounding our problem through a new method of accumulation with the credit and financial industries which Harvey and Marazzi detail in their work. Also, there is enough examples in there about the decline in manufacturing and the decline of accumulation and the lack of creating of surplus-value, but Harvey, more classically than Marazzi, describes this as an aspect within a continuation of neoliberal capitalist policies which is creating a new method of accumulation and Marazzi expands upon a similar point. Its not that a crisis is not happening but that this crisis is not so drastic to the entire enterprise of capital and that wealth is still steadily running upstream.

The question is, has capital found away to create surplus-value and overcome the small bump of the 70s and 80s, mean deregulation and the creation of an expanded global market, that I think is the question or what interests me with the conclusions I got from Aufheben.

S. Artesian

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on December 3, 2011

Very interesting. In the end it comes down to what it always comes down to in discussing "fictitious capital"-- does it create value.

Is Aufheben, or yourself claiming that structured investment vehicles, asset-backed securities, collateralized debt obligations are actual modes of producing value, or are they, as I think they are, vectors for claiming portions of the previously aggrandized value?

If the former, what causes the accumulation to stop? The answer I've seen all seem to revolve around underconsumption in some way shape or form. I think that is demonstrably mistaken. I think the financial sector is first and foremost, derivative in both good times and bad, and what determines whether times are good or bad is what has always determined whether times are good or bad-- the ability of capital to exploit labor [in production, in the production of use values] at a sufficient intensity to offset the tendency of the rate of profit to decline.

I don't think I shy away from discussing the financial sector as I think it is secondary, a "marker" so to speak, for what is really going on beneath the frenzy of arbitrage.

Marx-Trek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Marx-Trek on December 3, 2011

I am not sure within Aufheben's article or position on "fictitious capital" but Marazzi argues that there is no such thing as "fictitious capital" and that financialization of capitalism is an indication of that. Simply put, investment banks and Wall St. firms are no longer the only game in town, the financial sector is just as real in our lives, no longer some abstracted aspect of capitalism that doesn't have any "real" barring on our lives...

I think we have come full circle in our discussion where we disagree on the conclusion of what part the financial sector plays in the grand scheme of things.

As for under consumption theory, I am not totally sure what you mean exactly in regards to our discussion here, I see you are trying to use it as a form of a put down or suggesting that I am just holding onto some archaic notion...

Is Aufheben, or yourself claiming that structured investment vehicles, asset-backed securities, collateralized debt obligations are actual modes of producing value, or are they, as I think they are, vectors for claiming portions of the previously aggrandized value?

I am not sure what Aufheben is suggesting since, and you may agree with me, they abruptly ended their article with a point that leaves the reader asking for more information but only leads you to ask more questions to the answers you were looking for. Anyway, regardless of what Aufheben is suggesting, I found myself looking for the "long upturn" as you did, asking questions like, well if that is true where is it? If it exists then it has to be out there, China, Brazil, etc... or within credit and debt. As I said earlier, capitalism is a social relationship a material reality, so it can't be fake based on complete fraud and fantasy, or maybe that is the next stage???

So your question, is the financial sector a parasite or a site of accumulation and site of value production, well Marazzi would say it is a site of accumulation and place of value production. When this whole crisis began to unfold I found myself asking the question, how in the hell had capitalism found a way to make profit off of debt? It sounded contradictory, until I started to wrap my head around it. The interconnectedness of the entire capitalist mode of production has become financial that is how. Its not as if this aspect of the economy is just some parasite leeching off of real value production but rather is part of value production. It seems that credit and such things keep generating value off of things and I think here is where the idea of rent from the manuscripts of 1844 comes into play.

If capitalism is to generate surplus-value off credit/debt then the site of production is within the use of credit and creation of debt bundles that are then sold and thus completing the cycle of production and creation of surplus-value. Did you or anyone you know go further into debt today or some how take part in creating debt or perpetuating credit/debt? If so, you or they worked and got no pay for it. Or so it would seem. Is it simply fictitious or does it exist within the real market?

And here is the kicker, the EU, the US government, and the world have all talked big and loud about fixing this crisis and regulating these aspects of the financial market but in reality no government or regulatory agency has done shit, so it's still all in place and able to conduct itself in the same manner. The people's anger towards the banks and the financial sector is well founded but poorly places, what the banks do is what wal mart does, what fred perry does, there is no difference between banks, grocery stores, or clothing stores its all capital to create more capital.

Here in my town the big southern regional bank Wachovia went out of business and Wells Fargo is here now, no matter, it's the same shit, same credit/debt problem, the only change was the banks name. Now a couple of the public transit buses are totally wrapped in Wells Fargo ads and the ads suggest that they are different, PR doesn't translate into change.

baboon

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by baboon on December 3, 2011

I'm no financial expert but I tend to agree with S. Artesan's December 2 post and reject Marx-Trek's defence of a "new upturn". MT says that capitalism has a few problems but "it's not drastic". What's more capitalism can continue to accumulate capital by using bits of paper. Further, it can extract surplus value from these same bits of paper - in part anyway to be fair to MT. The other part could be the economic locomotive of "China or Brazil". Brazil as a locomotive of the world economy is not a new one on me and my reaction is not to give the idea any credibility whatsover. China? Already the "miracle" is slowing down and elements of the mass strike are sweeping backwards and forwards across the country. There's no new economic locomotive in the world anywhere.

Capitalism can't accumulate capital and extract surplus value from bits of paper - if it could, it wouldn't be capitalism. The extension of debt and credit (bits of paper) has been the "solution" and the problem for capitalism over the last fifty years, ie, since the late sixties. Since then there have been around 5 major recessions with economic storms hitting the capitalist "miracles"; Brazil was one in the 70s, then oil prices were blamed, then the Tigers and the Dragons were hit causing devastation. And from these shocks the crisis reverberating back to the capitalist metropoles (from where they largely emerged) and turned into global crises as a whole. Five major recessions from 1968 to the second millenium which, whatever the specificities of each one, show a trend, a very good indication of the direction that capitalism was and is taking. And each one of them "solved" by the extension of credit and debt which simply piled up greater problems further down the line to the point where we are today ("We don't know what's going to happen tomorrow", Mervyn King, Governor of the Bank of England).
The drug of credit has had to be increased over the decades to dope the system in the absence of real, viable markets. Whereas credit could provide a short-term palliative to expansion in times gone by, now the markets are finite and credit and debt become part of the problem.

I think that the bourgeoisie have been very intelligent in phasing in the crisis and dealing with dramatic events - for example US banks were effectively nationalised in 2008 and this indicates the universal tendency towards state capitalism. But while they can attempt to cohere there are counter-tendencies which come not least from capitalism's innate competitiveness and from the ruling class not really being in control. For example, last week the world's major bankers directed a lot of money, dollars mainly, towards Europe, in order, amongst other things, to underwrite the viability of ATM's!

The growth shown in the period 1945-68, mentioned above, was largely due to a post-war boom financed, in a never to be repeated effort by the US. After the war, Japan and Germany (and other parts of the world) were flattened and served, within the Marshall Plan, to motivate production. By the last years of the 60s, Japan and Germany became net exporters and the fundamental economic crisis of capitalism came back with a vengence. MT talks about "a small bump of the 70s and 80s" but this was a period of the beginning of this (today's) phase of the crisis and resulted in a massive attack on the working class throughout the world; wages were cut, real attacks on the social wage began and the rise in unemployment was a big shock. To call this "a small bump" is indicative of how the idea of an "upturn" divorces itself - in its academic cocoon - from reality.

MT says that the rich getting richer now (in relation to the poor) is a sign that everything must be alright with capitalism. Leaving aside the very restricted nature of this argument, I would see this as a further sign of a weakening economy and a historically bankrupt system.
What does MT have to say to workers today? From above it seems 'things are not so bad and they're going to get better'.

Marx-Trek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Marx-Trek on December 4, 2011

What does MT have to say to workers today? From above it seems 'things are not so bad and they're going to get better'.

Well, I would first have to breakdown your argument, before I tell you what I would say to workers (the two are connected), and since we are now speaking in open generalities (thank goodness), again we are no true economists, I can respond in plan generalities.

MT says that capitalism has a few problems but "it's not drastic"

Yes and no, I am suggesting that capitalism itself is not in crisis, but that there is a crisis within capitalism, and yes I agree this crisis is having devastating consequence for us all. But that is not my point or counterpoint. Only workers can take a crisis in capitalism and turn it into a crisis of capitalism. To say that there is a crisis within capitalism is drastically different than saying that capitalism is in crisis, I am not suggesting that capitalism is about to be toppled over by its own mechanisms, nor would I suggest any such toppling to occur without speaking on workers struggle and the difference between objective and subjective conditions/action.

Here is the problem with crisis theory or the declining profit rate theory is that it lacks the cause and effect of workers struggle within the capitalist social relationship, a dialectic. Your statement reflect an understanding of capitalism as some mindless zombie rather than the dynamic social relation it is. This crisis, dare I say, is not drastic, this crisis is not the end of capitalism because so far it is just our objective situation. Though the crises' effect on global markets and workers alike is drastic the crisis is not some cataclysmic event until workers make it so and until then crisis is just that crisis. No, I am not denying the consequence of crisis no matter how positive or negative, though I believe you are.

Here the decline in the rate of profit supporters seem to say 2+2= the end of capitalism. If capitalism is not such a dynamic force and just gets worse and worse, as so suggested by you, if I am allowed to generalize as much as you have been in making my counterpoint, then why are we not all starving to death and barely breathing because of the weight of capital bearing down on us...?

Could it be that crisis are an inherent aspect of capitalism but crisis not the negation of capital? So here I ask you again, where are the workers in your analysis and historical understanding of capitalism?

Now if we, the workers were to realize our objective conditions as oppressive in their totality, capitalism, and become active subjects then yes this crisis, the objective condition could in fact be the catalyst to our subjective actions against capitalism. Your concern with me and what I would say to the workers is appreciated but not necessary.

So here it goes, I would say,

"fellow workers, capitalism has placed us in such a precarious situation this day and age that we no longer feel a sense of attachment to our labor, no matter how alienated that feeling once was, in the past, because we could still see the creation of our labor power go out the door; but today we live in such hyper-alienation to the entirety of the capitalist system and production cycles that the reactionary in us has us wishing for the days of old alienation and production processes, at least that is the case here in the west. Our situation is so precarious and our jobs so insecure that we don't even know if we will be working in: warehouses, doing menial manual labor, changing tires, serving drinks, teaching, or going back to school to warehouse our hands and go into debt or borrow money we don't have. And on top of that the current barriers around organizing our labor power against capitalism has become some scattered and defuse that there no longer is a material vanguard which could strike out and deal a deathly blow to the entire cycle of capitalist production. Our historical movement for the future has resulted in one retreat and failure after another and the consequences have been dire. This is our crisis, the crisis of failed revolutions and the weakening of workers' power. Our failure to destroy capitalism in 1905, 1917, 1922, 1968, etc... has only resulted in Capitalist perfection of exploitation, production, accumulation, and alienation. We live in our failures and capitalism continues to profit. We must all strike out now, strike out now against capitalism no matter where you work or how you work! For we all work and are exploited, now more than ever! Destroy capitalism before it consumes your entirety!"

or the less soapbox version,

Throughout the history of the workers struggle against capitalism there have always been two forms of struggle: one of reform and the other of revolution. Capitalism is a social relationship in which we all live with but as workers it is in our interests to do away with capitalism. Historically, our movements have failed but or motives and desires are not part of those failures. The one crux in our history of movements is that capitalism emerges after revolutionary periods and incorporates the consequences of revolutionary periods and integrates these aspects into the production of surplus-value and pacifies the workers, but only momentarily. These moments of class recomposition are moments of learning for both the worker and capital, the struggle continues.

I think that the bourgeoisie have been very intelligent in phasing in the crisis and dealing with dramatic events - for example US banks were effectively nationalised in 2008 and this indicates the universal tendency towards state capitalism.

Regarding state-capitalism, well that is a discussion in and of itself for another time. There is no such thing as state-capitalism, capitalism is capitalism, nothing more nothing less. Looting public funds for private interest is not state-capitalism, it is capitalism.

To call this "a small bump" is indicative of how the idea of an "upturn" divorces itself - in its academic cocoon - from reality.

Lets not play academic vs. prol here, we all know that being a leftist of some sort takes time and energy both mental and manual energy. Either you got a formal education and incorporated your passion for revolution into your studies or you gave yourself an informal academic education by wrapping your head around grand ideas like dialectics, economics, and workers struggle. So spare me the academic trash talk, because: A. you or I don't know the other persons education background, B. you or I don't have any idea what kind of organizing or lives the others live, and C. there are both direct and indirect forms of knowing about something, and lets be honest either we learn our way to something or we experience our way to something.

But sense you started the whole, "this is academic and therefore it can't be a true expression of proletariat interests", let me interject and say, you are also being an example of the very thing you are trying to accuse me of, your argument doesn't take a deep enough look at the workings of capitalism in our everyday lives, you are abstracting our lives and simply saying it isn't so because it doesn't fit into your analysis of capitalism, its being dogmatic (I admit that the falling profit rate plays a role in capital looting public funds and cutting wages and I understand that making material things and selling them at a profit is part of the capitalist system, but I am also suggesting that capital is beyond just making cars, bombs, and oil. What is capitalism but producing something for profit? I don't really think, for capitalism, that there is a difference if profit is being made off credit/debt, prisoners, drugs, trees, cars, animals, or human labor-power having the only difference being how profit is made off these different commodites, is just a derivative as someone already said).

Which kind of brings us back to 2011, the worker, because of the material reality we live in is becoming an academic or college educated worker because capitalism needs it. There is a mountain of debt out there to prove it, and the debt is diverse and is traded on Wall St. Which kind of brings it all back into perspective.

MT says that the rich getting richer now (in relation to the poor) is a sign that everything must be alright with capitalism. Leaving aside the very restricted nature of this argument, I would see this as a further sign of a weakening economy and a historically bankrupt system.

A further sign of a weakening economy and a historically bankrupt system, well sure, if one day capitalism magically disappears, or do we the workers have to take an active role in capital's destruction?

What does MT have to say to workers today? From above it seems 'things are not so bad and they're going to get better'.

Do you really think my concern is whether or not things are going to get better or worse? If so, then you have really misunderstood what I am saying or I have been unable to clearly communicate.

Capitalism is a social relationship with deadly and rewarding consequences, the consequences are not the issue, the issue I have with capitalism is the command over life and the imposition of forced work placed upon all workers, work being the means to produce surplus-value and alienation experienced living within this production system. No matter how good or how bad things get within the capitalist system for all workers, there is still one constant, work, work which produces alienation and surplus-value.

Here is the perks of my perspective on capitalism over your declining rate of profit and dreary theory of gloom, the declining rate of profit is just a mechanism in place within the capitalist system which insures that profit and the most amount of profits at all times goes to the capitalist/capital though it is not man behind the curtain. I am not denying the declining rate of profit, I just don't see it as the end all be all of capitalism and its demise. Well, unless workers are the force behind the declining rate of profit...

Also, regarding objective and subjective situations, there is also the question, do objective conditions that produce revolutionary situations always result in revolutions? Lenin thought so. History tells us no.

Workers make history, but when will we make the future?

Marx-Trek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Marx-Trek on December 4, 2011

Maybe Aufheben and perspectives like it got tired or waiting for that declining rate of profit to hit rock bottom and somehow produce the worst living existence that we just have to revolt, since your declining rate of profit never seems to hit rock bottom anyhow.

S. Artesian

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on December 4, 2011

Marx-Trek

Maybe Aufheben and perspectives like it got tired or waiting for that declining rate of profit to hit rock bottom and somehow produce the worst living existence that we just have to revolt, since your declining rate of profit never seems to hit rock bottom anyhow.

There is no "rock bottom" to the tendency of the rate of profit to decline. Obviously, the bourgeoisie can survive on reduced rates of profit. However, there is no decline that the bourgeoisie can afford to ignore, to not respond to, to not attempt countervailing actions.

The argument is not "Is capitalism finished"? The issue is "is this an inflection point in a "long upturn"?

Marx-Trek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Marx-Trek on December 4, 2011

Well we can go back and forth again arguing that this is a downturn or a temporary downturn in a long upturn, which seems redundant.

I am currently reading Harvey's, The Enigma of Capital and he seems to combine both the upturn and the declining rate of profit ideas and then moves onto an idea of capital using barriers to overcome a decline in accumulation to then start new more profitable forms of accumulation. I am not finished with the book but its good so far.

we are revolutionaries not economists.

S. Artesian

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on December 4, 2011

Marx-Trek

we are revolutionaries not economists.

I'm not an economist. Neither was Marx. But there's an important point to the critique of capital and that critique requires being able to tell up from down, or more appropriately, speeding up from slowing down; heading up from turning down.

Actually, I'm kind of surprised by Aufheben's take on this. Some years ago, I thought Aufheben did a pretty good job of disputing Loren Goldners' "fictitious capital" arguments.

Now, it seems to me, Aufheben's position regarding financial instruments, paper claims, is that Loren was wrong in arguing about the "fictitious" part; that in fact finance represents something other than a mechanism for apportioning the already and anticipated value realization, and that something other is surplus value.

Marx-Trek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Marx-Trek on December 4, 2011

Through the years of reading Aufheben I have often found that their anaylsis, perspective , and polemics against other conclusions on any aspect of class struggle or anaylsis of capitalism picks apart certain aspects of various theoretical understandings of capitalism not to debunk but to expand.

Simply put, what is the end conclusion of the decline in the rate of profit? What happens after the capitalist cuts wages, cuts social welfare, and destroys commodity surplus?

Marx-Trek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Marx-Trek on December 4, 2011

"The capital-labor relations always plays a central role in the dynamics of capitalism and may lie at the root of crises. But these days the main problem lies in the fact that capital is too powerful and labor too weak, rather than the other way around."

-David Harvey, The Enigma of Capital.(p.66).

S. Artesian

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on December 4, 2011

Marx-Trek

Through the years of reading Aufheben I have often found that their anaylsis, perspective , and polemics against other conclusions on any aspect of class struggle or anaylsis of capitalism picks apart certain aspects of various theoretical understandings of capitalism not to debunk but to expand.

Simply put, what is the end conclusion of the decline in the rate of profit? What happens after the capitalist cuts wages, cuts social welfare, and destroys commodity surplus?

War and revolution; if we're lucky war or revolution.

Marx-Trek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Marx-Trek on December 5, 2011

socialism or barbarism, sorry, not that type of end conclusion, to far ahead, I was thinking about what is the conclusion of the decline in the rate of profit? Like generally speaking, does the declining rate of profit suggest that the decline is constant, like crack, once you smoke that first time you are constantly chasing that high. So for capitalism, capitalism will never reach that high in accumulation again? Is that the general conclusion for the declining rate of profit theory?

The declining rate of profit theory is still the same right?

baboon

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by baboon on December 5, 2011

Academicism first: for me it's not a matter of anyone's education, of personalities, or professors against proletarians, but the concept of an upturn, as expressed above, being academic. This fits in with not seeing any objective economic contradictions within the capitalist system - which, in certain historical circumstances, I think is the basis for social revolution. If the production of commodities and their sale, doesn't, of itself, lead to economic crisis and decay, then why not socialist production of commodities using money and value?

Secondly, I don't subscribe to the falling rate of profit analysis as the explanation of capitalism's crisis. It's part of it - and you don't seem to reject it entirely MK - but for me the problem is the restricted market. And it is in response to this latter, in order to conjure up a false market, that the bourgeoisie has, over the last fifty years, embarked on the extensions of credit and debt. I don't at all see credit and debt as commodities similar to oil, automobiles, trees, even drugs but as symptoms of a system in terminal decline which tries to overcome the problem (for capitalism) of a finite globe by turning fresh air (or paper of electronic money) into a phoney market. If in 1960 the amount of world debt was 100, today it stands at 250.This is totally unsustainable and points to extreme fissures in the system that can only get worse.In 2008, the major states saved the banking system. Three years down the road and the most powerful states are themselves in debt - who is going to save them? Not the banks. Any sort of increase in growth today, any new upturn, would require a further massive increase in credit and debt which itself (as we've seen with quantatative easing) would not guarantee or underwrite any increase in production but would be guaranteed to fuel inflation. We've seen this with the monetary mass increasing in the USA by a factor of 3 and x2 in the eurozone. It's done nothing except buy a little time.

I don't understand what you are saying about there being a crisis but not a crisis; it's drastic but not drastic; and if there is a crisis why aren't we dying of hunger? For a start there is a great many of the masses that are already dying of hunger, along with dying of trivial (and serious) sicknesses and the effects of imperialist war. If the main battalions of the working class are reduced to dying of hunger then we are all finished.

State capitalism doesn't exist you say - just the looting of state coffers but state capitalism is a clear historical development of a crisis-ridden system: Stalinism, fascism (the slogan of the Third Reich for example was "export or die"), the New Deals, public works, state subsidies, Keynsianism and the welfare states of the democracies. The war economy and the tendency of capitalism to ever increase the methods of destruction were somewhat lifted after the first world war but were reinforced and remain a stronger tendency since the crisis of the 30s and particularly after WWII. Since then US imperialism engineered the world according to its interests and this has been, even though contributing to the economic crisis, a continuing feature.All states have centralised around their national interests even if those interests are expressed by neo-liberal elements. Even with the development of state capitalism the crisis tends to move out of the control of the ruling class. The dollar has been the final guarantor of payment since 1945 and underwritten the circulation of commodities and capital but, given the accumulation of US debt, those dollars today are declining " toxic assets".

As to the question at what point does the economic crisis (whether falling rate of profit or whatever) turn into generalised imperialist war then there's no mechanical link, there's no formula. I think that MK is correct about "socialism or barbarism" and we can already see growing elements of the latter, certainly on the peripheries. In the meantime, in the capitalist centres, the interest payments alone on debt are looking increasingly tenuous. What do the bourgeoisie do: increase debt as a substitute for a solvent market with all the attendent and growing risks or go for austerity; wage-cuts, unemployment and cut backs to the point today that, if not starving, the basic needs of the working class can no longer be met? This is an economic crisis that is fundamental to the whole system.

S. Artesian

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on December 5, 2011

Marx-Trek

socialism or barbarism, sorry, not that type of end conclusion, to far ahead, I was thinking about what is the conclusion of the decline in the rate of profit? Like generally speaking, does the declining rate of profit suggest that the decline is constant, like crack, once you smoke that first time you are constantly chasing that high. So for capitalism, capitalism will never reach that high in accumulation again? Is that the general conclusion for the declining rate of profit theory?

The declining rate of profit theory is still the same right?

The tendency to decline is constant; as are the bourgeoisie's attempts to offset that tendency. That's where it gets us. Structural deceleration or decline, cyclical contraction, leading to destruction of the elements of production, human and mechanical.

Marx-Trek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Marx-Trek on December 6, 2011

wow, interesting, your saying that "upswing theory" or my position are academic because they don't realize contradictions within capitalism? Aufheben can speak for itself regarding their view on contradictions within capitalism.

Yes of course there are contradictions within capitalism but they themselves do no produce revolutions, look at history. Again, there are the objective conditions (work, lay offs, stock market crash, bubbles,etc...) which produce the conditions for social revolt but the revolt is not a guarantee. Then there are our, the workers' subjective action which is taken in response or in reaction to the objective conditions and those actions can either revolution or anything else, such as reforms or nothing. There are revolutionary situations which can, and I hope, produce revolutionary practice.

As for contradiction, the mother of all contradiction which gets compartmentalized over and over again, workers vs. capital (workers producing everything collectively so that it can be consumed privately). What more contradiction do you need? Again, I am glad you are concerned but there is no need I am aware of contradictions.

Secondly, I don't subscribe to the falling rate of profit analysis as the explanation of capitalism's crisis.

Then why did you subscribe to it a couple of posts ago?

And then you go on to say that credit/debt are, "symptoms of a system in terminal decline," which again confuses me since here are going back to the idea that capitalism is in a terminal state. So either the impending doom resulting from the continuing decline in the rate of profit will happen or not?

As for state-capitalism, If capitalism cared as much about the purity of its capitalist ideology as it did about surplus-value and profit they would make less, thus ideology is only secondary.

On crisis, this is a crisis within capitalism a recession or a problem in making money,momentarily, not denying that; but this crisis is not the crisis that will end capitalism. It will only become the crisis that ended capitalism when we the workers make a qualitative leap in our struggles and become active subjects against capitalism. If we don't do this, resist, than this will just be another crisis in a long list of crises.

It seems that your analysis or conclusion lacks workers' activity and organizing against capitalism because crisis, according to your argument, is brought on by the mechanism of itself: false money, credit default swaps,etc... but where are the workers? If contradictions are in play what role do workers have in producing those contradictions and expanding on those contradictions.

So shall we go around in circles again?

baboon

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by baboon on December 6, 2011

I've looked at history and seen that the contradictions of capitalism do produce major working class movements, insurrections and revolutions.
But go around in circles again? No. I give my opinion and you tell me what I really think.

Marx-Trek

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Marx-Trek on December 6, 2011

Sorry, I am not wanting to talk over anyone, I apologize if that is how I am coming off.

The going around in circles comments are in response to our conversation and what I see as rehashing arguments again and again, I don't mean it as an attack on you but as a pattern that is being developed in conversation. There seems to be differences in opinion between you, SA, and I and that is fine but I find it confusing when you say you support the idea of a declining rate of theory as so being argued by SA, then you don't, and then you do again. Could you clarify what you mean?

As for history, the history of contradictions and revolutions have produced revolts and struggle, but I would say that it is the activity of workers that has produced, compounded, and expanded on contradictions and created revolutions, not the declining rate of profit. The declining rate of profit could be an indicator of struggle or just a sign of capitalism doing something. Objective conditions are just that but our actions regarding those conditions is what is central to me understanding of possible revolts and a better future.

I am suggesting that the declining rate of profit is not some happening prophecy which charts, percentages, and graphs which measures the impending doom of capitalism. Rather, the declining rate of theory is just an indication of a decline in the rate of profit, that may or may not, bean indicator of revolt, working class organizing, and general anti capitalist antagonisms (active or just reacative) baked into the system from the get go.

S. Artesian

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by S. Artesian on December 6, 2011

I am suggesting that the declining rate of profit is not some happening prophecy which charts, percentages, and graphs which measures the impending doom of capitalism. Rather, the declining rate of theory is just an indication of a decline in the rate of profit, that may or may not, bean indicator of revolt, working class organizing, and general anti capitalist antagonisms (active or just reacative) baked into the system from the get go

I've never claimed that the TFROP is a prophecy which measures the impending doom of capital.

I have claimed that TFROP does put the lie to the claim that the current moment represents an "inflection point" in the "long upturn" of capitalism.

baboon

13 years ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by baboon on December 7, 2011

I re-read the posts MT and I did give the impression that I agreed with all that SA said - so the apology is from me. What I agreed with SA were elements of his analysis, including some of the falling rate of profit, and his argument against the idea of a "long-term upturn" coming out of capitalism.

To clarify my views further: How, why and when - the mechanics of capitalist decay work themselves out is uncertain but what for me is certain is the certainty of death. The potential clash of the two major classes doesn't just come about from their existence or from the unfairness of it from a proletarian point of view but because capitalism, as well as creating its own "gravedigger" carries within its political economy the seeds of its own destruction. The main reason, in my opinion, for its transitory nature, is the overproduction of commodities, overproduction in relation to effective demand which itself is underwritten by an ability to pay. This necessarily, continuously restricts production, which, in the first place could be overcome by the destruction of value (expressed in idle units of production), eliminating competition and thus increasing the rate of profit overall. But these elements themselves only paved the way for further wider and deeper crises within the system overall.

The idea that there is no innate crisis of capitalism was argued by bourgeois economists like Say and Ricardo (whose work Marx used well) who saw capitalist crises in terms of contingent factors: speculation, disproportionality between branches, poor harvests, devaluation, falling prices, etc. But the market could overcome these problems and move into further areas of growth, again paving the way for more extensive crises. Specifically, in relation to Ricardo, Marx argued that capitalism contained within itself a barrier to the development of the productive forces in that "overproduction - the basic phenomenon in crises" (Theories of Surplus Value, part two, chapter XXVII). The proletariat, as long as it produces surplus value, must always over-produce above their needs in order to consume within those limits.
This phenomenon did not exist in previous societies, which Marx also saw as transitory, though Marx notes the tendencies in these societies to the over-consumption of the rich, which in the decay and decompositon of Greece and then Rome, reached "mad extravagance".

The overproduction innate to capitalism finds its extreme in the relative saturation of a limited, finite globe from which production based on capital can only go so far in expanding into. It must then devour parts of itself which we see with the development of imperialism which was both a palliative and then a further expression of deeper crises. The driving necessity for increasing the ratio between machinery and living labour tends to cause the value in each commodity to shrink and the rate of profit to fall: a barrier which "... testifies to the limitations and to the merely historical transitory character of the capitalist mode of production" (Capital, Vol. 3, chapter XXV).

Capitalism has developed all sorts of attenuations and schemas to overcome its fundamental contradictions but they all pile up problems further down the road. And here, again, I agree with elements of SA: none of this, the falling rate of profit, the market, give a clearly charted measurement of the collapse of capitalism so that we can fixate on such and such a point. There is no mechanical determination here - just the certainty of more profound crises and decay. I entirely agree with you about the primacy of the proletarian struggle but this in itself comes out of the objective situation. Rather than "War or Revolution" or even "Socialism or Barbarism", I think that Marx's Communist Manifesto statement about the system culminating "either in a revolutionary reconstitution of society at large, or in the common ruin of contending classes..." is more apt.

Marx-Trek

12 years 12 months ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Marx-Trek on December 8, 2011

An interesting and very concisely written response, and I too want to clarify that I am not totally opposed to the declining rate of profit as a real development within the workings of capitalism but don't see myself grounded or rooted in the larger conclusions.

I think we all could agree that its us, the workers mission to build on and seek out the most advanced and militant struggle against whatever objective conditions that is produced within capitalism because after all it is us who have to suffer the consequence of losing battles within the class war.

Marx-Trek

12 years 12 months ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by Marx-Trek on December 8, 2011

So, to paraphrase, B, it seems that you believe that revolution will definitely happen due to the the consequences of the constant over-production by workers for capital to obtain surplus-value; since one day there will be a point at which workers are unable to over-produce due to the extravagant amount of surplus-value the workers will have to produce to keep capitalism afloat, and that such a situation will then result in revolution.

I too hope that such a materialist guarantee is embedded in capitalism but fear that capitalism is a beast that will do anything to remain, and it is this dynamic and ever-changing social relationship that lead me to believe that there is always the possibility for revolution but it is not a guarantee. Capital's demise rests on the subjective actions of our class, which is a reaction to the objective conditions.

I do not exclude the thought that workers can choose to revolt whenever they want, despite of an ongoing crisis or not, nor do I think that you exclude workers own ability to fight, but I do think that we, the Marxists/revolutionaries do put to much focus on crisis, as if crisis is step one in revolution. Crisis is just an objective condition, like going to work, but we tend to us crisis as talking points to show how bad capitalism truly is, when crisis is "just" part of Capital. I feel as if a lot of this crisis talk, take Occupy for example, tries to make connections down at the socially lowest common denominator which does not address the entirety but one aspect, the crisis at hand.

I generally agree that crisis are opportunities but if we are to be part of an anti-capitalist force we have to be more proactive rather than reactive.

baboon

12 years 12 months ago

In reply to by libcom.org

Submitted by baboon on December 9, 2011

MT, just to attempt to clarify some confusion around my position expressed in your first paragraph:

Firstly, I don’t believe revolution will definitely happen... From where we are today, the working class could be gradually isolated, divided and ground down with decisive defeats in important areas here and there. In such a situation it will be the left and the unions that will facilitate such a defeat.
However much, in the absence of a proletarian response, the ruling class is able to pauperise the working class – or fall into some form of generalised warfare – the same problems, only worse will still exist for capitalism. Hence the mutual ruin of contending classes.

Secondly, if a revolution were to happen, it will be because things can no longer go on as they are. Whatever one’s analysis of the cause of the economic crisis of capitalism and its relationship to the class struggle, there is no doubt that the perspective is for it to adversely affect the conditions of the working class and the greater numbers of populations. When the shock waves of the 2007/8 economic upheavals hit Chinese capitalism a month or two later, 20 million Chinese workers lost their jobs. The effects of the crisis on the working class are massive and point to what it has to do. If there is no crisis, if capitalism is not finished as a social system, there can be no revolution in my opinion. For me the fundamental economic contradiction of capitalism is that there are no more markets for it to expand into in order to continue to accumulate capital. Profit from surplus value in fundamental to the problem and it’s here that the tendency of the rate of profit to fall becomes a further factor.
I know that it’s much more complicated than this, but essentially capitalism is a glorified pyramid scheme, a Ponzi confidence trick that is kept going not by absorbing new entrants and new elements and thus productive returns, but unsustainable mountains of debt that it providing to itself.
Once again; there is no mechanical link, no predetermined tripping point between crisis and class struggle but the link is undeniable.

It’s the same for imperialist war. After World War I, which was basically a battle for existing markets (rather than fighting over new, colonial spoils), it was clear in the workers’ movement that if capitalism wasn’t done away with, new, more destructive wars would break out. Again there was no formula, no specific tripping mechanism – just that they would happen. The Third International, at the height of its clarity, was particularly clear on this even if nobody could say how, when and with whom a new war would happen. We know that World War II came directly from the economic crisis of the 1930s, autarky, defence of the national interest, etc. This resulted in the squeezing of Germany and the latter’s break out for “living space” and to take back markets under the Third Reich’s slogan of “Export of Die”.
If we are not threatened with global warfare today – and every major imperialism is now engaged in upgrading their nuclear arsenals and delivery systems – then localised warfare is still a constant threat to the working class as well as being a further factor in the exacerbation of the crisis.